No. 02-682
In the Supreme Court of the United States
VERIZON COMMUNICATIONS INC., PETITIONER
v.
LAW OFFICES OF CURTIS V. TRINKO, LLP
ON WRIT OF CERTIORARI
TO THE UNITED STATES COURT OF APPEALS
FOR THE SECOND CIRCUIT
BRIEF FOR THE UNITED STATES
AND THE FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
AS AMICI CURIAE SUPPORTING PETITIONER
THEODORE B. OLSON
Solicitor General
Counsel of Record
R. HEWITT PATE
Acting Assistant Attorney
General
WILLIAM E. KOVACIC
General Counsel
Federal Trade Commission
Washington, D.C. 20403
PAUL D. CLEMENT
Deputy Solicitor General
JEFFREY A. LAMKEN
Assistant to the Solicitor
General
CATHERINE G. O’SULLIVAN
NANCY C. GARRISON
DAVID SEIDMAN
Attorneys
Department of Justice
Washington, D.C. 20530-0001
(202) 514–2217
QUESTION PRESENTED
Whether the court of appeals erred in reversing the district court’s dismissal of respondent’s antitrust claims.
(I)
TABLE OF CONTENTS
Page
Interest of the United States and the Federal Trade
Commission .............................................................................
Statement ........................................................................................
Summary of argument ..................................................................
Argument:
The 1996 Telecommunications Act neither modifies
the Sherman Act nor eliminates the requirement that
plaintiffs show exclusionary conduct ..................................
I. The 1996 Act neither bars nor supports claims
alleging Sherman Act violations ..................................
II. The court of appeals erred in failing to require
exclusionary conduct under Section 2 of the
Sherman Act ....................................................................
A. Exclusionary conduct is essential to any
Section 2 claim premised on unilateral
action ..........................................................................
1. Monopolization and attempted monopolization require exclusionary conduct .............
2. In cases asserting a duty to assist rivals,
conduct is exclusionary only if it would
not make economic sense but for the
tendency to impair competition ....................
B. The court of appeals improperly applied the
“essential facilities” doctrine to dispense with
the exclusionary conduct requirement ................
C. The court of appeals’ application of “monopoly leveraging” is inconsistent with
Section 2 principles .................................................
(III)
1
1
6
8
9
13
13
14
15
20
25
IV
Table of Contents—Continued:
D. Under the proper standards of Section 2
liability, respondent’s complaint fails to
state a claim ..............................................................
Conclusion .......................................................................................
Page
27
30
TABLE OF AUTHORITIES
Cases:
AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366 (1999) ............ 2, 18, 21
Advanced Health-Care Servs. v. Radford Cmty.
Hosp., 910 F.2d 139 (4th Cir. 1990) ....................................
16
Allied Tube & Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc.,
486 U.S. 492 (1988) .................................................................
15
Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp.,
472 U.S. 585 (1985) .......................................................... passim
Associated Press v. United States, 326 U.S. 1
(1945) ........................................................................................
24
Berkey Photo, Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 603
F.2d 263 (2d Cir. 1979), cert. denied, 444 U.S. 1093
(1980) ...................................................................................... 18, 27
Blue Cross & Blue Shield United v. Marshfield Clinic,
65 F.3d 1406 (7th Cir. 1995), cert. denied, 516 U.S.
1184 (1996) ............................................................................. 18-19
Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco
Corp., 509 U.S. 209 (1993) ...................................................
20
California Motor Transp. Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 404 U.S. 508 (1972) ................................................
15
Cavalier Tel. Co. v. Verizon Va., Inc., No. 02-1337,
2003 WL 21153305 (4th Cir. May 20, 2003) ....................... 11, 12
Conley v. Gibson, 355 U.S. 41 (1957) ..................................
28
Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp.,
467 U.S. 752 (1984) ............................................................
13, 15
Covad Communications Co. v. BellSouth Corp., 299
F.3d 1272 (11th Cir. 2002), petition for cert. pending, No. 02-1423 (filed Mar. 20, 2003) .................................
11
V
Cases—Continued:
Page
DM Research, Inc. v. College of American Pathologists, 170 F.3d 53 (1st Cir. 1999) ........................................
29
Delaware & Hudson Ry. v. Consolidated Rail Corp.,
902 F.2d 174 (1990) ................................................................
29
Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs.,
Inc., 504 U.S. 451 (1992) ......................................................
13
General Indus. Corp. v. Hartz Mountain Corp., 810
F.2d 795 (8th Cir. 1987) ........................................................
16
Goldwasser v. Ameritech Corp., 222 F.3d 390
(7th Cir. 2000) ...............................................................
11, 18, 30
Hishon v. King & Spalding, 467 U.S. 69 (1984) ...............
29
Kartell v. Blue Shield of Mass., Inc., 749 F.2d 922 (1st
Cir. 1984), cert. denied, 471 U.S. 1029 (1985) ...................
19
Laurel Sand & Gravel, Inc. v. CSX Transp., Inc.,
924 F.2d 539 (4th Cir.), cert. denied, 502 U.S. 814
(1991) ....................................................................................
22, 23
MCI Communications Corp. v. AT&T, 708 F.2d
1081 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 464 U.S. 891 (1983) ............. 21, 22
Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v. Zenith Radio Corp.,
475 U.S. 574 (1986) ................................................................
16
MetroNet Servs. Corp. v. US West Communications, 325 F.3d 1095 (9th Cir. 2003) ...................................
11
Olympia Equip. Leasing Co. v. Western Union Tel.
Co., 797 F.2d 370 (7th Cir. 1986) ........................................ 10, 23
Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366
(1993) ........................................................................................
22
Papasan v. Allain, 478 U.S. 265 (1986) .............................
29
Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. AT&T, 740
F.2d 980 (D.C. Cir. 1984), cert. denied, 470 U.S.
1005 (1985) ...........................................................................
12, 24
Spectrum Sports, Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447
(1993) ..............................................................................
13, 14, 26
Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1
(1911) .................................................................................. 1, 10, 13
Stearns Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 170
F.3d 518 (5th Cir. 1999) ........................................................
16
VI
Cases—Continued:
Page
Swierkiewicz v. Sorema, 534 U.S. 506 (2002) ....................
28
Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17
(1st Cir. 1990), cert. denied, 499 U.S. 931 (1991) ..............
12
United States v. AT&T:
524 F. Supp. 1336 (D.D.C. 1981) ..........................................
24
552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff ’d, 460 U.S. 1001
(1983) ........................................................................................
2
United States v. ALCOA, 148 F.2d 416 (2d Cir.
1945) .....................................................................................
14, 15
United States v. Griffith, 334 U.S. 100 (1948) ...............
14, 27
United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253 F.3d 34 (D.C.
Cir.), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952 (2001) ...............................
14
United States v. Otter Tail Power Co., 331 F. Supp.
54 (D. Minn. 1971) ..............................................................
22, 23
United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass’n, 224 U.S. 383
(1912) ........................................................................................
24
Verizon Communications, Inc. v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467
(2002) ...........................................................................
2, 3, 9, 10
17, 18, 30
Viacom Int’l, Inc. v. Time Inc., 785 F. Supp. 371
(S.D.N.Y. 1992) ......................................................................
22
Virgin Atl. Airways Ltd. v. British Airways PLC,
257 F.3d 256 (2d Cir. 2001) ...................................................
26
Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. & Chem.
Corp., 382 U.S. 172 (1965) ...................................................
14
Statutes and rule:
Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C. 151 et seq.:
47 U.S.C. 202 ..........................................................................
5
Sherman Act § 2, 15 U.S.C. 2 ............................................ passim
Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104,
110 Stat. 56 ........................................................................ passim
47 U.S.C. 152 note (§ 601(b), 110 Stat. 143) ................ 3, 11,
18, 25, 30
47 U.S.C. 251 ......................................................................
3, 5
47 U.S.C. 251(c) .................................................................
30
VII
Statutes and rule—Continued:
47 U.S.C. 251(c)(2) .............................................................
47 U.S.C. 251(c)(4) .............................................................
47 U.S.C. 252 ......................................................................
47 U.S.C. 252(c)(3) .............................................................
47 U.S.C. 271 ......................................................................
Fed. R. Civ. P. 8(a)(2) ...............................................................
Page
2
2
3
2
4
28
Miscellaneous:
ABA Section on Antitrust, Antitrust Law Developments (5th ed. 2002) ............................................................ 12, 26
P. Areeda, The “Essential Facility” Doctrine: An
Epithet in Need of Limiting Principles, 58 Antitrust
L.J. 841 (1989) .........................................................................
21
P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law (2d ed.
2002):
Vol. 1A ................................................................................
12
Vol. 3 ..........................................................................
14, 22, 26
Vol. 3A ................................................................... 8, 10, 17, 21
Letter from Robert A. Curtis, President Z-Tel Network
Services, CC Docket No. 01-338 (Sept. 23, 2002) .............
3
Order Approving Interconnection Agreement, Case
No. 09-C-0723 (N.Y. Pub. Serv. Comm’n June 13,
1997), available in 1997 WL 410707 ....................................
3
L. Sullivan & W. Grimes, The Law of Antitrust
(2000) ........................................................................................
17
INTEREST OF THE UNITED STATES AND THE
FEDERAL TRADE COMMISSION
The United States and the Federal Trade Commission
have primary responsibility for enforcing the federal antitrust laws, and thus a strong interest in the correct application of those laws.
STATEMENT
This case concerns the relationship between the Nation’s
antitrust laws and the Telecommunications Act of 1996 (1996
Telecommunications Act or 1996 Act), Pub. L. No. 104-104,
110 Stat. 56 (47 U.S.C. 251 et seq.). The 1996 Act requires incumbent local exchange carriers to share their facilities with
rivals on certain terms. The question presented concerns
whether the antitrust laws impose similar duties.
1. Section 2 of the Sherman Act, 15 U.S.C. 2, makes it
unlawful for any firm to “monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce
among the several States, or with foreign nations.” Section 2
does not specify the elements of monopolization and attempted monopolization. It is nonetheless well established
that Section 2 does not prohibit monopoly status in and of
itself. Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 62
(1911). Rather, Section 2 makes it unlawful to acquire or
maintain monopoly power through predatory or exclusionary
conduct. See Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen Highlands Skiing
Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 602 (1985). That prohibition is most
often enforced through negative duties, i.e., by requiring
firms to refrain from anticompetitive conduct directed
against rivals. But in limited circumstances, Section 2 may
impose an affirmative duty to deal with or assist rivals.
While the antitrust laws provide a general framework for
the protection of competition, the 1996 Telecommunications
Act imposes detailed duties on certain market participants in
order to change the competitive structure of the telecom-
(1)
2
munications industry. See Verizon Communications, Inc. v.
FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 475, 489 (2002). The current structure of
that industry is in part a product of the 1982 consent decree
that settled the United States’ antitrust suit against AT&T.
United States v. AT&T, 552 F. Supp. 131 (D.D.C. 1982), aff’d,
460 U.S. 1001 (1983). That decree separated AT&T’s longdistance and equipment units from the units that provided
local telephone service, and barred the latter from providing
long-distance telephone service except in limited circumstances. See Verizon, 535 U.S. at 475.
Since then, the incumbent local exchange carriers
(ILECs), such as the Bell Companies that inherited AT&T’s
local telephone franchises, have remained dominant in the
provision of local telephone service. The 1996 Act seeks to
introduce competition into local exchange and related markets by requiring ILECs to assist potential rivals by “shar[ing] their own facilities and services on terms to be agreed
upon with new entrants.” Verizon, 535 U.S. at 476. In addition, the 1996 Act empowered the FCC to “prescribe
methods for state commissions to use in setting rates that
would subject both incumbents and entrants to the risks and
incentives that a competitive market would produce.” Ibid.
Roughly speaking, new entrants may obtain the use of an
incumbent’s local telephone network in three ways. First,
they may purchase an incumbent’s local telephone service at
a wholesale rate and resell it. 47 U.S.C. 251(c)(4). Second,
they may build their own facilities and “interconnect” them
with the incumbent’s network. 47 U.S.C. 251(c)(2). And
third, they “may choose to lease” some or all of the components of the incumbent’s network—known as “network elements”—“which the incumbent has a duty to provide ‘on an
unbundled basis’ at terms that are ‘just, reasonable, and
nondiscriminatory,’ ” 47 U.S.C. 252(c)(3). See Verizon, 535
U.S. at 491-492; AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366, 371
(1999). The 1996 Act provides that new and incumbent
carriers must negotiate critical terms in good faith. Verizon,
3
535 U.S. at 492-493. If they fail to agree, either may seek
mediation or arbitration by the public utilities commission of
the relevant State. Ibid. In furtherance of the goal of
“jumpstart[ing]” competition, the 1996 Act provides pricing
rules that require incumbents to provide unbundled elements at rates that will “attract new entrants when it would
be more efficient to lease than to build or resell.” Id. at 539.
The resulting pricing rules may require ILECs to provide
new entrants with access to the local telephone network at
rates that are below the ILEC’s historical cost. Id. at 497498. The resulting rates may also generate less revenue for
the ILEC than would selling to retail customers directly.1
The 1996 Act includes an antitrust savings clause,
§ 601(b), 110 Stat. 143. It declares that, “except as provided”
in provisions not relevant here, “nothing in this Act * * *
shall be construed to modify, impair, or supersede the applicability of any of the antitrust laws.” 47 U.S.C. 152 note.
2. This case arises out of a dispute between AT&T, which
is a competitive local exchange carrier (CLEC), and petitioner Verizon Communications Inc., an ILEC. The dispute
involves petitioner’s performance of an agreement with
AT&T for telephone service in the State of New York following negotiation and binding arbitration pursuant to 47
U.S.C. 251 and 252. See Pet. App. 5a, 22a; Order Approving
Interconnection Agreement, Case No. 96-C-0723 (N.Y. Pub.
Serv. Comm’n June 13, 1997) (available in 1997 WL 410707).
1 For example, petitioner asserts that it can earn substantially more
by selling its services at retail than it does by leasing facilities at “unbundled network element” rates to competitors. See Pet. Cert. Reply 5
n.5. For present purposes, it is sufficient to observe that the 1996 Act’s
pricing standards are not designed to ensure that ILECs earn the same
revenues selling to competitors as they do by serving retail customers
directly. As one competitive local exchange carrier told the FCC, the Act
shifts ILECs “from a high margin retail base to lower-margin wholesale
business.” Letter from Robert A. Curtis, President, Z-Tel Network
Services, CC Docket No. 01-338, at 7 (Sept. 23, 2002).
4
The agreement specifies the terms under which petitioner is
to provide AT&T with the use of petitioner’s local telephone
network so that AT&T can sell local telephone service in
competition with petitioner. The agreement also specifies
dispute-resolution procedures that are “the exclusive remedy for all disputes between” petitioner and AT&T “arising
out of th[e] [a]greement or its breach.” Pet. App. 5a (quoting
1997 WL 410707, at *23). On March 9, 2000, the FCC and
petitioner entered into a consent decree resolving the FCC’s
investigation into petitioner’s potential violations of Section
271 of the 1996 Act. The decree required that petitioner,
among other things, pay $3 million to the United States, and
petitioner agreed to pay $10 million to AT&T and other
CLECs. Pet. App. 5a, 50a.
One day after the FCC issued the consent decree, respondent filed this putative class action lawsuit. Pet. App. 51a.
Respondent is an AT&T customer, id. at 5a, but has no apparent business relationship with petitioner. The complaint
alleged:
[Petitioner] has not afforded CLECs access to the local
loop on a par with its own access. Among other things,
[petitioner] has filled orders of CLEC customers after
fulfilling those for its own local phone service, has failed
to fill in a timely manner, or not at all, a substantial number of orders for CLEC customers substantially identical
in circumstances to its own local phone service customers
for whom it has filled orders on a timely basis, and has
systematically failed to inform CLECs of the status of
their customers’ orders with [petitioner].
Id. at 6a (quoting J.A. 39 (Am. Compl. ¶ 21)); see J.A. 46-47
(Am. Compl. ¶ 54).
Respondent did not allege in the complaint that petitioner
had failed to fill, or had delayed filling, any order relating to
its own AT&T local telephone service. Respondent instead
alleged that petitioner’s conduct had affected its “ability
* * * to obtain satisfactory Local Phone Service,” and injured
5
petitioner’s competitors “in the provision of ” local phone
service. J.A. 47 (Am. Compl. ¶ 57). Respondent further
alleged that petitioner’s conduct “had no valid business
reason and was intended to exclude competition * * * ‘by
making it difficult for competitors to provide service in the
Local Phone Service market on the level that [petitioner] is
able to provide to its customers in that market.’ ” Pet. App.
6a-7a (quoting J.A. 46 (Am. Compl. ¶ 52)). Respondent
asserted a treble damages claim under Section 2 of the
Sherman Act. Id. at 6a.2
The district court dismissed the complaint. Pet. App. 49a61a. After holding that respondent had standing under the
Sherman Act, id. at 53a-54a, the court concluded that the
complaint did not state a claim because the only anticompetitive conduct it identified was petitioner’s “failure
* * * to cooperate with competing local carriers” as required
by 47 U.S.C. 251. Id. at 53a. “The affirmative duties imposed by the Telecommunications Act,” the court observed,
“are not coterminous with the duty of a monopolist to refrain
from exclusionary practices.” Id. at 54a.
Respondent amended the complaint, adding allegations
that petitioner breached its contracts with CLECs “with the
purpose of acquiring or maintaining monopoly power in the
local phone service market.” Pet. App. 63a. The district
court again dismissed the complaint. Id. at 64a-68a. The
court noted that, under respondent’s Sherman Act theory,
“when a firm with enough market power” and anticompetitive intent “breache[s] the terms of contracts it has with
competitors that assist those competitors,” it “violates Section 2 of the Sherman Act.” Id. at 66a. The antitrust laws,
the court observed, do not put monopolists under a general
duty to cooperate with competitors. The district court
2
Respondent also asserted claims under the Communications Act of
1934, 47 U.S.C. 202, and the 1996 Act. The reformulated question presented does not encompass those claims.
6
therefore held that the alleged breaches of contract “were
not ‘anticompetitive’ conduct within the meaning of the
antitrust laws.” Id. at 67a.
3. The court of appeals affirmed in part and reversed in
part. Pet. App. 1a-48a. The court of appeals agreed that respondent had antitrust standing. Id. at 26a-27a. The court
of appeals disagreed, however, with the district court’s
holding that respondent’s complaint is insufficient to “support an antitrust claim.” Id. at 29a. Instead, the court held
that the complaint “may state a claim under the ‘essential
facilities’ doctrine,” under which “a monopolist has a duty to
provide competitors with reasonable access to * * * facilities
under the monopolist’s control and without which one cannot
effectively compete in a given market.” Ibid. Alternatively,
the court concluded that respondent “may have a monopoly
leveraging claim,” which could be established by showing
that “the defendant ‘(1) possessed monopoly power in one
market; (2) used that power to gain a competitive advantage
. . . in another distinct market; and (3) caused injury by
such anticompetitive conduct.’ ” Id. at 30a.
SUMMARY OF ARGUMENT
I. Telecommunications firms must comply with both the
1996 Telecommunications Act and the Sherman Act. As the
antitrust savings clause in the 1996 Act makes clear, that
Act neither restricts the scope of the antitrust laws by conferring implied immunity, nor expands antitrust liability by
creating new antitrust duties that did not exist before the
1996 Act’s passage.
II. A. Although the court of appeals in form acknowledged the distinction between the 1996 Act and the Sherman
Act, in substance it conflated the two. To “jump-start” competition, the 1996 Act requires incumbent local exchange
carriers to “share” their facilities with new entrants, offering
them access equivalent to the incumbent’s, at regulated
7
rates. But conduct that violates the obligations imposed by
the 1996 Act does not ipso facto violate the antitrust laws.
To the contrary, unilateral conduct can violate Section 2 of
the Sherman Act—it can constitute monopolization or attempted monopolization—only if it is exclusionary or predatory. In the context of an alleged refusal to assist a rival,
conduct is exclusionary only if it would not make business or
economic sense apart from its tendency to reduce or eliminate competition. That demanding standard is necessary to
ensure that the Sherman Act promotes competition. A more
generalized duty would rarely enhance consumer welfare
and would threaten to impair the competition the antitrust
laws are designed to promote.
B. The court of appeals erred in displacing the requirement of exclusionary conduct with the so-called essential facilities doctrine. That doctrine does not establish an independent antitrust tort; it describes certain types of monopolization and attempted monopolization cases. Essential
facilities cases, like all other Section 2 cases, require proof of
exclusionary conduct.
C. The court of appeals similarly erred in failing to require exclusionary conduct in connection with so-called “monopoly leveraging” claims. The court of appeals’ leveraging
theory would effectively create a new category of antitrust
liability for monopolists that gain a competitive advantage
—such as that which results from economies of scope or
scale—unless they “share” that advantage with competitors.
The Sherman Act prohibits exclusionary conduct that perpetuates or threatens to create monopoly; it does not prohibit failure to share monopoly power.
D. The complaint in this case fails to allege exclusionary
conduct and thus fails to state a claim. The complaint does
not allege circumstances suggesting that petitioner’s failure
to assist rivals by providing them with access to its network,
on the terms and at the rates required by the 1996 Act,
would not make business sense apart from the effect on
8
competition, the pertinent standard here. For example, it
nowhere asserts that, by refusing to sell to competitors as a
wholesaler at regulated rates, instead of serving customers
itself as a retailer, petitioner undertook a sacrifice of shortterm profits that would make sense only if it had the effect of
impairing competition. Nor does the complaint address the
cost of providing competitors with wholesale access as
required by the Act. Contrast Aspen Skiing Co. v. Aspen
Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 608, 610-611 (1985)
(conduct that imposed a “sacrifice” of “short-run benefits”
and made sense only because it “reduc[ed] competition * * *
over the long run”); 3A P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law ¶ 773, at 211 (2d ed. 2002) (“[N]o firm has a
general duty to injure itself in order to benefit a rival.”).
Instead, the complaint rests on the assumption that any
conduct that violates the 1996 Act necessarily violates the
antitrust laws. Because that assumption is incorrect, and
because the complaint fails to allege a sufficient basis for
finding the conduct exclusionary, the court of appeals erred
in sustaining it.
ARGUMENT
THE 1996 TELECOMMUNICATIONS ACT NEITHER
MODIFIES THE SHERMAN ACT NOR ELIMINATES
THE REQUIREMENT THAT PLAINTIFFS SHOW EXCLUSIONARY CONDUCT
A straightforward reading of the Telecommunications Act
of 1996 and the Sherman Act makes clear that firms in the
telecommunications industry must conform their conduct to
the requirements of both of those Acts, for both Acts apply.
The court of appeals correctly so held. The Acts, however,
impose distinct requirements, such that a violation of one is
not ipso facto a violation of the other. While the court of appeals recognized that in form, in substance it applied mistaken antitrust standards that effectively conf late the duties
imposed by the two Acts.
9
The district court dismissed the complaint in this case because respondent failed to allege “exclusionary” practices.
The court of appeals did not disagree that the complaint
failed to plead such practices. The court of appeals reversed
nonetheless because, in its view, Sherman Act liability could
be sustained under two alternative theories—“essential
facilities” and “monopoly leveraging”—without showing exclusionary conduct. Those theories, however, do not provide
stand-alone bases for liability under Section 2, and they do
not permit liability absent proof of exclusionary conduct.
The Sherman Act prohibits anticompetitive restraints of
trade. It is not a license for federal courts to create codes of
desirable business conduct under which competitors must
assist each other for the public good.
I. The 1996 Act Neither Bars Nor Supports Claims
Alleging Sherman Act Violations
The 1996 Act and the Sherman Act implement the national commitment to competitive markets in fundamentally
different ways. The 1996 Act was “intended to eliminate the
monopolies enjoyed by the inheritors of AT&T’s local franchises; [an] objective * * * considered both an end in itself
and an important step toward the Act’s other goals of
boosting competition in broader markets and revising the
mandate to provide universal telephone service.” Verizon
Communications v. FCC, 535 U.S. 467, 476 (2002). The Act
thus sought to “uproot[]” local telephone monopolies, id. at
488, and to “reorganize” and “bring competition to localexchange markets,” id. at 489, 539, without regard to whether ILEC monopolies developed and persisted lawfully in
the first instance. To achieve that end, the 1996 Act provides a detailed blueprint under which ILECs must assist
their rivals to “jumpstart” competition. See id. at 488. It
requires ILECs, for example, to “lease elements of their networks” to their competitors “at rates that would attract new
entrants when it would be more efficient to lease than to
10
build or resell.” Id. at 539. The resulting “wholesale market
for leasing network elements” and resulting pricing structures are “brand new.” Id. at 528; pp. 1-3 & note 1, supra.
Section 2 of the Sherman Act, in contrast, proscribes conduct that monopolizes, i.e., monopolization or attempted monopolization. It thus does not prohibit or condemn “monopoly in the concrete.” Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221
U.S. 1, 62 (1911)). And it neither expressly mandates the
sharing of an incumbent firm’s facilities nor provides concrete pricing and access rules for such sharing. That is
because, unlike the 1996 Act, the Sherman Act does not
impose a generalized duty to assist rivals, much less a
generalized duty to assist them by sharing facilities at rates
that are “attractive” or on terms different from those offered
to non-competitor customers. See Aspen Skiing Co. v.
Aspen Highlands Skiing Corp., 472 U.S. 585, 600-601 (1985);
see also Olympia Equip. Leasing Co. v. Western Union Tel.
Co., 797 F.2d 370, 375-376 (7th Cir. 1986) (Section 2 imposes
on a monopolist “no general duty to help its competitors” and
“no duty to extend a helping hand to new entrants”). Simply
put, the Sherman Act does not require firms—whether or
not monopolists—to sacrifice profits to sell to competitors at
a discount. 3A P. Areeda & H. Hovenkamp, Antitrust Law
¶ 773, at 211 (2d ed. 2002) (“[N]o firm has a general duty to
injure itself in order to benefit a rival.”); see id. ¶ 772, at 188
(Aspen Skiing “certainly does not hold that a monopolist
must make its goods, services, or facilities available at a
competitive rather than a monopolistic price.”).
Although the two statutes adopt different strategies to
promote competition, Congress intended them to coexist.
The more specific provisions of the 1996 Act provide detailed
obligations that ILECs must meet. But the 1996 Act does
not by its terms bar application of the Sherman Act to the
same sphere of conduct or provide immunity from Section 2
prosecutions. To the contrary, the 1996 Act includes a
savings clause that recognizes that the antitrust laws impose
11
distinct obligations and that neither set of laws displaces the
other. Specifically, the 1996 Act provides (with certain
exceptions not applicable here) that it should not “be construed to modify, impair, or supersede the applicability of
any of the antitrust laws.” 47 U.S.C. 152 note. Recognizing
the import of that language, the decision below correctly
held that the 1996 Act does not immunize conduct from
antitrust scrutiny. See Pet. App. 32a. The other courts of
appeals have uniformly reached the same conclusion. See
Goldwasser v. Ameritech Corp., 222 F.3d 390, 401 (7th Cir.
2000) (suggestion that the 1996 Act confers “implied immunity on behavior that would otherwise violate the antitrust
law * * * would be troublesome at best given the antitrust
savings clause in the statute”); Covad Communications Co.
v. BellSouth Corp., 299 F.3d 1272, 1280-1281 (11th Cir. 2002),
petition for cert. pending, No. 02-1423 (filed Mar. 20, 2003);
MetroNet Servs. Corp. v. US West Communications, 325
F.3d 1086, 1099-1101 (9th Cir. 2003); Cavalier Tel. Co. v.
Verizon Va., Inc., No. 02-1337, 2003 WL 21153305, at *10
(4th Cir. May 20, 2003).
Conversely, the 1996 Act does not expand the scope of the
antitrust laws to outlaw conduct that, but for the 1996 Act,
would not violate the antitrust laws. Such an expansion of
Sherman Act duties would “modify * * * the applicability of
* * * the antitrust laws” in contravention of 47 U.S.C. 152
note. Violations of the duties imposed by the 1996 Act are
just that—violations of the 1996 Act, subject to the sanctions
and penalties imposed by that Act. They do not automatically amount to treble-damages antitrust claims. The
courts of appeals are again in accord. Pet. App. 29a; Covad,
299 F.3d at 1283 (“[W]e agree with Goldwasser that merely
pleading violations of the 1996 Act alone will not suffice to
plead Sherman Act violations.”); Goldwasser, 222 F.3d at 400
(It is “both illogical and undesirable to equate a failure to
comply with the 1996 Act with a failure to comply with the
12
antitrust laws.”); Cavalier Tel. Co., 2003 WL 21153305, at
*11-*12 (similar).3
Instead, whether ILEC conduct violates the antitrust
laws must be determined according to antitrust standards.
That is not to say that the presence of regulation is irrelevant. Regulation may affect the economic analysis of an industry, sometimes substantially. Regulation may, for
example, render certain business propositions unattractive
where, but for regulation, they might be attractive, or vice
versa. And regulation might alter likely competitive consequences. As then-Judge Breyer observed in a case concerning a so-called “price squeeze,” price regulation “dramatically alters the calculus of antitrust harms and benefits” by
“significantly diminish[ing] the likelihood of major economic
harm.” Town of Concord v. Boston Edison Co., 915 F.2d 17,
25 (1st Cir. 1990), cert. denied, 499 U.S. 931 (1991). But regulation does not necessarily eliminate the risk of monopolization; nor does it obviate the need for antitrust analysis.
See id. at 28 (limiting holding to the “ordinary” case); Southern Pac. Communications Co. v. AT&T, 740 F.2d 980, 1001
(D.C. Cir. 1984), cert. denied, 470 U.S. 1005 (1985).
In all events, the effect of regulation on the incentives for
and the economic consequences of particular conduct is
highly fact and industry specific. 1A Areeda & Hovenkamp,
supra, ¶ 240d, at 17-18. The mere existence of a regulatory
structure, even the detailed structure established by the
3
In other contexts not implicated here, courts have sometimes found
that the violation of other extrinsic duties—such as prohibitions against
fraud and deception—may be a significant factor when ascertaining
whether the conduct is exclusionary for antitrust purposes. See ABA
Section on Antitrust, Antitrust Law Developments 249 (5th ed. 2002)
(“where conduct contributes to establishing or maintaining monopoly
power, a court will be especially likely to find conduct predatory or
anticompetitive if it is also improper for reasons extrinsic to the antitrust
laws”); Cavalier, 2003 WL 21153305, at *13 (holding does not preclude
consideration of extrinsic duties outside 1996 Act context); see also pp. 1415 note 4, infra.
13
1996 Act and the FCC’s implementing regulations, does not
de facto create antitrust immunity for otherwise anticompetitive conduct. To the extent petitioners contend otherwise, see Pet. 8-9, they are mistaken. But equally important,
the 1996 Act does not create an antitrust minefield in which
any regulatory violation by a monopolist substitutes for a
showing of exclusionary conduct.
II. The Court of Appeals Erred In Failing To Require
Exclusionary Conduct Under Section 2 Of The
Sherman Act
Although the court of appeals correctly recognized the
distinction between the 1996 Act and the Sherman Act as a
matter of form, in substance it imported 1996 Act duties into
antitrust law. The Sherman Act may require a dominant
firm to deal with competitors in limited circumstances. But
the court of appeals’ decision unduly expands those circumstances by endorsing “essential facilities” and “monopoly
leveraging” theories uncabined by the requirement of
exclusionary or predatory conduct.
A. Exclusionary Conduct Is Essential To Any Section
2 Claim Premised On Unilateral Action
Section 2 of the Sherman Act specifies two offenses that
can be committed by a firm acting unilaterally—monopolization and attempted monopolization. See Spectrum Sports,
Inc. v. McQuillan, 506 U.S. 447, 459 (1993) (citing Copperweld Corp. v. Independence Tube Corp., 467 U.S. 752, 767769 (1984)). As this Court made clear long ago, Section 2
does not prohibit monopoly as such, i.e., “monopoly in the
concrete.” Standard Oil Co. v. United States, 221 U.S. 1, 62
(1911). Rather, the offense of monopolization is broadly defined as (1) the willful acquisition or maintenance of monopoly power (2) by the use of anticompetitive conduct “to foreclose competition, to gain a competitive advantage, or to destroy a competitor.” Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 482-483 (1992) (quoting United
14
States v. Griffith, 334 U.S. 100, 107 (1948)); see United States
v. ALCOA, 148 F.2d 416, 432 (2d Cir. 1945).
1. Monopolization and Attempted Monopolization Require
Exclusionary Conduct
A sine qua non for any claim of monopolization or attempted monopolization is conduct that “reasonably appear[s] capable of making a significant contribution to
creating or maintaining monopoly power.” 3 Areeda &
Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 651f, at 83-84; Spectrum Sports, 506
U.S. at 458-459. Even where actions threaten to create or
maintain a monopoly, only “exclusionary” or “predatory”
conduct is proscribed by Section 2. Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S.
at 602. The conduct must “not only (1) tend[] to impair the
opportunities of rivals, but also (2) either * * * not further
competition on the merits or do[] so in an unnecessarily restrictive way.” Id. at 605 n.32.
Applying that standard “can be difficult,” because “the
means of illicit exclusion, like the means of legitimate competition, are myriad.” United States v. Microsoft Corp., 253
F.3d 34, 58 (D.C. Cir.) (en banc), cert. denied, 534 U.S. 952
(2001). However, it does not entail open-ended “ ‘balancing’
of social gains against competitive harms,” for “a firm is under no obligation to sacrifice its own profits” for the public
weal. 3 Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶¶ 651a, 658f, at 72,
131-132, 135. Instead, the harm to competition must be disproportionate to consumer benefits (in terms of providing a
superior product, for example) and to the economic benefits
to the defendant (aside from benefits that accrue from
diminished competition). See ibid. Under that standard,
this Court has recognized a variety of anticompetitive means
by which defendants may seek or maintain monopolies.4
4
For example, the enforcement of a fraudulently obtained patent may
amount to exclusionary conduct under Section 2 if it has the requisite
effect on competition. See Walker Process Equip., Inc. v. Food Mach. &
Chem. Corp., 382 U.S. 172, 177-178 (1966). Likewise, sham litigation or
15
The requirement of exclusionary conduct emanates from
the Sherman Act itself. Imposing liability in the absence of
exclusionary conduct risks discouraging, even punishing, the
very competition the antitrust laws are intended to encourage. This Court has noted the difficulty of “distinguish[ing] robust competition from conduct with long-run
anti-competitive effects.” Copperweld, 467 U.S. at 767-768.
Indeed, the conduct of a vigorous competitor may “appear[]
to ‘restrain trade’ unreasonably” even where that conduct “is
precisely the sort of competition that promotes the consumer
interests that the Sherman Act aims to foster.” Id. at 767.
Thus, “[s]ubjecting a single firm’s every action to judicial
scrutiny for reasonableness would threaten to discourage the
competitive enthusiasm that the antitrust laws seek to
promote.” Id. at 775. As Judge Hand wrote, “[t]he successful
competitor, having been urged to compete, must not be
turned upon when he wins.” ALCOA, 148 F.2d at 430.5
2. In Cases Asserting A Duty To Assist Rivals, Conduct
Is Exclusionary Only If It Would Not Make Economic
Sense But For The Tendency To Impair Competition
Where, as here, the plaintiff asserts that the defendant
was under a duty to assist a rival, the inquiry into whether
conduct is “exclusionary” or “predatory” requires a sharper
focus. In that context, conduct is not exclusionary or predatory unless it would make no economic sense for the defendant but for its tendency to eliminate or lessen competition.
bad-faith contact with administrative agencies may create a substantial
anticompetitive impact in violation of Section 2. See, e.g., California
Motor Transp. Co. v. Trucking Unlimited, 404 U.S. 508 (1972). And the
private standard-setting process may afford opportunities for opportunistic behavior that may harm competition. See, e.g., Allied Tube &
Conduit Corp. v. Indian Head, Inc., 486 U.S. 492 (1988).
5 Different considerations apply to concerted action, which is
“inherently * * * fraught with anticompetitive risk.” Copperweld, 467
U.S. at 768-769. As a result, concerted action is evaluated for its
reasonableness—and is, in some instances, summarily condemned as
illegal per se.
16
This Court has emphasized that sort of analysis with respect to predatory pricing. Matsushita Elec. Indus. Co. v.
Zenith Radio Corp., 475 U.S. 574, 588-589 (1986); ABA
Section on Antitrust, Antitrust Law Developments 247 (5th
ed. 2002) (“courts have held conduct to be predatory where it
would be economically irrational for the monopolist but for
the conduct’s adverse impact on competition”). In that
context, this Court has expressed concern that conduct perfectly consistent with robust competition—“cutting prices in
order to increase business”—should not lightly give rise to
antitrust liability, because doing so may “chill the very
conduct that antitrust laws are designed to protect.”
Matsushita, 475 U.S. at 594. Price cuts, moreover, rarely
harm consumers, because “predatory pricing schemes are
rarely tried, and even more rarely successful.” Id. at 589.
Likewise, in the context of asserted duties to assist rivals,
this Court and the courts of appeals have recognized that
conduct is exclusionary where it involves a sacrifice of shortterm profits or goodwill that makes sense only insofar as it
helps the defendant maintain or obtain monopoly power. See
Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S. at 608, 610-611 (conduct that “sacrifice[s] short-run benefits,” such as immediate income and
consumer goodwill, undertaken because it “reduc[es] competition * * * over the long run”); General Indus. Corp. v.
Hartz Mountain Corp., 810 F.2d 795, 803 (8th Cir. 1987)
(conduct anticompetitive if “its ‘anticipated benefits were
dependent upon its tendency to discipline or eliminate competition and thereby enhance the firm’s long term ability to
reap the benefits of monopoly power.’ ”); see also Stearns
Airport Equip. Co. v. FMC Corp., 170 F.3d 518, 523-524 &
n.3 (5th Cir. 1999) (conduct exclusionary if it harms the
monopolist but is justified because it causes rivals more
harm); Advanced Health-Care Servs. v. Radford Cmty.
Hosp., 910 F.2d 139, 148 (4th Cir. 1990) (“making a shortterm sacrifice” that “harm[s] consumers and competition” to
further “exclusive, anti-competitive objectives”). In con-
17
trast, a refusal to aid rivals that makes economic or business
sense apart from a tendency to impair competition is not
exclusionary.
That demanding standard, like the one employed in the
predatory pricing context, reflects the infrequent pro-competitive benefits and the frequent anticompetitive risks
posed by a generalized requirement that firms assist rivals.
Consumers are generally “no better off when a monopoly is
shared; ordinarily, price and output are the same as they
were when one monopolist used the input alone.” 3A Areeda
& Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 771b, at 171-172. At the same time,
dealings among rivals create a risk of collusion. Id. ¶ 772c4,
at 191-192 (discussing “Collusion risks”); see Aspen Skiing,
472 U.S. at 598 n.22. That alone renders lawsuits premised
on a failure to cooperate with rivals troublesome.
Even in the absence of collusion, dealings among rivals
can have the unintended consequence of forestalling rather
than promoting competition. A firm that has the right to
utilize an input from an incumbent—or that can claim that
right through litigation—may have a reduced financial incentive to develop the input itself. 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp,
supra, ¶ 771b, at 172 (“[T]he right to share * * * discourages firms from developing their own alternative inputs.”);
Verizon, 535 U.S. at 550 (Breyer, J., concurring and dissenting in part) (sharing of facilities is not “consistent with
* * * competition,” although competition may emerge with
respect to elements that are not shared); see id. at 551, 560;
see also L. Sullivan & W. Grimes, The Law of Antitrust § 3.4,
at 112 (2000) (“Compelling a monopolist to grant competitors
access to a facility that the monopolist has alone developed is
problematic” because it “collides with” the “commonplace
propositions” that “not even monopolists need give positive
assistance to competitors” and “that innovation should be
encouraged and rewarded.”). Finally, mandated sharing
could impose substantial administrative burdens for courts.
“Even the simplest kind of compelled sharing * * * means
18
that someone must oversee the terms and conditions of that
sharing.” AT&T v. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. 366, 428 (2000)
(Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part).
Congress and regulatory agencies, of course, may identify
circumstances where it is economically efficient to require
the incumbent to share its facilities under a system of price
and access regulation; or where new entrants should be
permitted to use the monopolist’s facilities while establishing
themselves, and their customer base, before they are expected to build their own facilities. Indeed, the 1996 Act
rests in part on that kind of industry-specific determination.
See Verizon, 535 U.S. at 510-511 & n.27; Cavalier Tel. Co.,
2003 WL 21153305, at *11 (1996 Act a “distinctly different
approach to jump-start and accelerate competition”); Goldwasser, 222 F.3d at 399 (similar). But the identification and
remediation of those situations is best dealt with through
industry-specific legislation and regulation—like the 1996
Act—which can be developed by legislative branches and
administrative agencies with superior factfinding ability,
greater industry expertise, existing capacity for ongoing
oversight and refinement, and the public accountability that
is an important companion to such economic policy choices.
But where, as here, Congress enacts a regulatory structure
that imposes affirmative obligations to assist rivals and
expressly disclaims any intent to “modify * * * the
applicability of any of the antitrust laws,” 47 U.S.C. 152 note,
it is clearly inappropriate for a court automatically to
perceive antitrust consequences from regulatory violations.
Instead, the antitrust laws generally afford all firms—including monopolists—great discretion in determining with
whom they will and will not deal. Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S. at
600-603. They also permit firms to charge whatever prices
they can obtain in the marketplace. Berkey Photo, Inc. v.
Eastman Kodak Co., 603 F.2d 263, 274 n.12 (2d Cir. 1979),
cert. denied, 444 U.S. 1093 (1980); Blue Cross & Blue Shield
United v. Marshfield Clinic, 65 F.3d 1406, 1413 (7th Cir.
19
1995) (“the antitrust laws are not a price-control statute or a
public-utility or common-carrier rate-regulation statute”),
cert. denied, 516 U.S. 1184 (1996); Kartell v. Blue Shield of
Mass., Inc., 749 F.2d 922, 927 (1st Cir. 1984) (Breyer, J.)
(“even a monopolist is free to exploit whatever market
power it may possess” by “charging uncompetitive prices”),
cert. denied, 471 U.S. 1029 (1985).
Nonetheless, a monopolist’s right to refuse cooperation
with rivals is not wholly unqualified. Aspen Skiing, 472 U.S.
at 600-601. If such a refusal involves a sacrifice of profits or
business advantage that makes economic sense only because
it eliminates or lessens competition, it is exclusionary and
potentially unlawful. In Aspen Skiing, for example, this
Court upheld a verdict against the Ski Co., which had terminated its former cooperation with a smaller rival, Highlands,
and refused numerous proposals for resumed cooperation.
In finding sufficient evidence that the Ski Co.’s conduct could
“properly be characterized as exclusionary,” 472 U.S. at 605,
this Court repeatedly stressed that the Ski Co.’s decision to
refuse cooperation required the sacrifice of immediate profits. The Ski Co., for example, refused to sell its lift tickets to
its rival at full price, “forgo[ing] daily ticket sales” and the
goodwill of its own customers, who were inconvenienced by
that choice. Id. at 608; id. at 593 & n.14 (Ski Co. refused to
sell to its competitor “any lift tickets” of its own, “either at
the tour operator’s discount or at retail”). The Ski Co.
“elected to forgo these short term benefits,” the evidence
showed, “because it was more interested in reducing competition in the Aspen market over the long run by harming its
smaller competitor.” Id. at 608; see id. at 610 (offers rejected
by Ski Co. “would have entailed no cost to Ski Co. itself,
would have provided it with immediate benefits, and would
have satisfied its potential customers”); id. at 610-611 (Ski
Co. “was willing to sacrifice short-run benefits and consumer
goodwill in exchange for a perceived long-run impact on its
smaller rival”). Moreover, Ski Co. could not satisfactorily
20
explain how its conduct made economic sense apart from the
harm to competition. Id. at 608. The conduct was thus condemned because it made no economic sense but for its anticompetitive consequences.
When, on the other hand, a monopolist’s refusal to deal
(or, as here, breach of an agreement to deal) on particular
terms does make business sense apart from exclusionary
consequences, antitrust law should avoid interfering with
such business choices. At one extreme, a refusal to sell an
input to a rival when it requires the incumbent to forfeit
profits would make obvious business sense. But even in less
extreme circumstances, courts should be hesitant to impose
a duty to assist rivals. The decisions of a seller, even a monopolist, regarding to whom it will sell, on what terms, and
under what sort of quality and purchaser-satisfaction measures, generally reflect its own assessment of how to compete
and provide goods most effectively in the marketplace.
There is good reason to be cautious when setting the standard under which such conduct is condemned as exclusionary, lest consumers be deprived of the benefits of pro-competitive business practices, or potential competition be displaced by cooperation as would-be rivals share inputs. See
Brooke Group Ltd. v. Brown & Williamson Tobacco Corp.,
509 U.S. 209, 224 (1993); pp. 15-18, supra.
B. The Court of Appeals Improperly Applied The “Essential Facilities” Doctrine To Dispense With The Exclusionary Conduct Requirement
Departing from that approach, some courts of appeals
have developed an “essential facilities” doctrine divorced
from traditional antitrust requirements, including proof of
exclusionary conduct. As articulated by those courts, the
doctrine requires a monopolist to assist rivals by sharing a
facility if, by refusing to do so, the monopolist can “extend
monopoly power from one stage of production to another”
and the following four elements are found:
21
(1) control of the essential facility by a monopolist; (2) a
competitor’s inability practically or reasonably to duplicate the essential facility; (3) the denial of the use of the
facility to a competitor; and (4) the feasibility of providing the facility.
MCI Communications Corp. v. AT&T, 708 F.2d 1081, 11321133 (7th Cir.), cert. denied, 464 U.S. 891 (1983). See 3A
Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 771a, at 169-170; see also P.
Areeda, The “Essential Facility” Doctrine: An Epithet in
Need of Limiting Principles, 58 Antitrust L. J. 841 (1989).
This Court has never adopted the essential facilities doctrine in a Section 2 case. Iowa Utils. Bd., 525 U.S. at 428
(Breyer, J., concurring in part and dissenting in part). And
the doctrine has been heavily criticized. See, e.g., 3A Areeda
& Hovenkamp, supra, ¶ 771c, at 173 (“the essential facility
doctrine is both harmful and unnecessary and should be
abandoned”). That criticism is well-founded. Requiring a
firm to share its monopoly with its competitors, as the essential facilities doctrine does, can be inconsistent with the fundamental, pro-competitive goals of the antitrust laws. Id.
¶ 771b, at 171; see pp. 17-18, supra.
The problem, however, is not so much that the four factors
articulated by the MCI decision are irrelevant; they can be
helpful. See p. 22 note 6, infra. Rather, the difficulty is that
federal courts have sometimes articulated the essential
facilities doctrine and the four factors as if they described a
stand-alone antitrust violation, untethered to traditional
Sherman Act requirements. See 3A Areeda & Hovenkamp,
supra, ¶ 772, at 175 (doctrine not “an independent tool of
analysis but only a label—a label that beguiles some commentators and courts into pronouncing a duty to deal without analyzing the implications”). Section 2, however, prohibits only acts that constitute “monopolization” or “attempts to monopolize.” It does not establish essential facilities violations as an independent antitrust tort. The four factors identified in MCI and other decisions thus are relevant
22
but neither necessary nor sufficient to establish Section 2
liability.6 As one court has explained, the essential facilities
doctrine is “a label that may aid in the analysis of a monopoly
claim, not a statement of a separate violation of law.” Viacom Int’l, Inc. v. Time Inc., 785 F. Supp. 371, 376 n.12
(S.D.N.Y. 1992). It relieves plaintiffs “of no burden they
would otherwise bear, and constitutes no substitute for a
showing that the requirements of a cause of action under the
antitrust laws have been met.” Ibid. Consequently, as with
any other monopolization or attempted monopolization claim,
so-called essential facilities claims must include some showing of “exclusionary” or “predatory” conduct. In this context, that means conduct that would not make sense but for
its tendency to reduce or eliminate competition.7
6
The first two factors—that the facility (1) is controlled by a monopolist, and (2) cannot be duplicated by those seeking to compete in a related
market—may help identify circumstances in which a refusal to deal might
“reasonably appear capable of making a significant contribution to
creating or maintaining monopoly power.” 3 Areeda & Hovenkamp,
supra, ¶ 651f, at 83-84. The fourth requirement in particular—the feasibility of providing the access that was refused—relates to whether the
defendant’s conduct may be viewed as exclusionary, but does not itself
demonstrate it. Cf. Laurel Sand & Gravel, Inc. v. CSX Transp., Inc., 924
F.2d 539, 545 (4th Cir.) (feasibility of providing access must be analyzed in
the context of the monopolist’s normal course of business), cert. denied,
502 U.S. 814 (1991); MCI, 708 F.2d at 1133 (“No legitimate business or
technical reason was shown for AT&T’s denial of the requested interconnection”; “MCI was not requesting preferential access”; MCI was not
“asking that AT&T in any way abandon its facilities”); id. at 1144
(allegation that AT&T had sold the requested access “to local customers,
independent phone companies and other[]” non-competitors “for years”).
7 Otter Tail Power Co. v. United States, 410 U.S. 366 (1973), is not to
the contrary. Otter Tail was not based on an “essential facilities” theory
of liability, and the trial court found that the sole reason for the conduct
there was to prevent erosion of monopoly power. See id. at 378; see also
United States v. Otter Tail Power Co., 331 F. Supp. 54, 61 (D. Minn. 1971)
(“defendant has a monopoly * * * and has consistently refused to deal
with municipalities which desired to establish municipally owned systems
on the alleged justification that to do so would impair its position of dom-
23
For that reason, a monopolist’s refusal to sell his goods or
services below the monopoly price would not ordinarily be
actionable, because that price maximizes profits apart from
its effect on competitors in related markets. See pp. 18-19,
supra. Whether that price is above the price set by regulators or higher than the would-be competitor is willing to pay
is irrelevant. Laurel Sand & Gravel, Inc. v. CSX Transp.,
Inc., 924 F.2d 539, 545 (4th Cir.) (rejecting view that essential facilities doctrine requires that access be provided to a
monopolist’s competitor on terms that would permit the
competitor to make a profit), cert. denied, 502 U.S. 814
(1991). Indeed, the contrary rule would not merely require
the monopolist to share its facility. It would, in effect, require the monopolist to share its profits.8
In this case, the court of appeals focused on the existence
of a so-called essential facility and lost sight of the need for
exclusionary conduct. It thus treated the essential facilities
doctrine as a free-standing basis for Sherman Act liability,
on a par with monopolization and attempted monopolization,
but without examining the standards applicable to those offenses. In particular, the court of appeals deemed it sufficient that the complaint alleged that the local loop was es-
inance in selling power at retail to towns in its service area”). The
defendant, which was already in the business of wheeling power, not only
refused to deal, but also demanded and enforced anticompetitive
provisions in contracts with potential competitors. 410 U.S. at 378-379.
8 For that reason—and because of the difficulties inherent in determining the price and other terms a non-exclusionary monopolist would
demand—the circumstance most likely to lead to liability is “a monopoly
supplier’s discriminating against a customer because the customer has
decided to compete with it.” Olympia Equip., 797 F.2d at 377 (emphasis
added). The monopolist’s willingness to offer non-competitors particular
terms is evidence that those terms are profitable to it, and that the refusal
to offer the same terms to competitors represents a sacrifice of immediate
profits that would not make sense but for the tendency to impair
competition. Judge Posner has therefore described such discrimination as
the “essential feature of the refusal-to-deal cases.” Ibid.
24
sential to competing in the local phone service market; that
recreating the local loop was prohibitively expensive; and
that petitioner denied AT&T, a competitor, “reasonable
access” to the loop. Pet. App. 29a-30a.
The court of appeals contemplated that petitioner might
eventually escape liability if it established either that the
local loop was in fact not essential, or that it actually had
provided “reasonable access.” Pet. App. 30a. But the court
did not address whether the complaint alleged exclusionary
or predatory conduct. Furthermore, it appears to have
assumed that “reasonable access” means access on the terms
provided under the 1996 Telecommunications Act rather
than access on such terms as would make business sense
apart from their effect on competition, such as those offered
to non-competitor customers.9 That inappropriately imports
Telecommunications Act duties and standards into the antitrust laws, violating the 1996 Act’s instruction that “nothing
9
The court of appeals interpreted the essential facilities doctrine to
require that access be provided on “just and reasonable terms” placing
all—apparently including the monopoly supplier of the facility—on an
“equal plane.” Pet. App. 29a. That language, however, is not drawn from
standards relating to antitrust liability but from the remedial requirements this Court addressed in United States v. Terminal R.R. Ass’n, 224
U.S. 383, 411 (1912). See Southern Pac. Communications Corp., 740 F.2d
at 1008-1009; United States v. AT&T, 524 F. Supp. 1336, 1352-1353 (D.D.C.
1981). Terminal Railroad, moreover, was not based on an essential
facilities theory of liability. That case concerned whether “unification of
substantially every terminal facility by which the traffic of St. Louis is
served resulted in a combination which is in restraint of trade.” 224 U.S.
at 394. Nor was a denial of access at issue there, since the fact “[t]hat
other companies are permitted to use the facilities of the Terminal Company upon paying the same charges paid by the proprietary companies
seem[ed] to be conceded.” Id. at 400. The Court chose to impose a requirement of equal access on reasonable terms as part of a remedial
scheme because it found that dissolving the combination would be
injurious to the public. Id. at 409-411; Associated Press v. United States,
326 U.S. 1, 25 (1945) (Douglas, J., concurring) (Terminal Railroad “held
that as an alternative to dissolution a plan should be submitted which
provided for equality of treatment of all railroads.”).
25
in” it “shall be construed to modify * * * the applicability
of any of the antitrust laws.” 47 U.S.C. 152 note. By
equating the specific regulatory duties of affirmative
assistance imposed by the 1996 Act with conduct required to
avoid Sherman Act liability, the court misconceived the distinct purpose of the 1996 Act.10 That Act’s requirements
reflect a variety of regulatory objectives. The specific duty
to assist competitors by leasing access to the local loop was
not designed merely to protect competition, but to restructure an entire industry by, among other things, encouraging
new entry; consequently, the Act in some circumstances
imposes duties to assist rivals on terms that are more
favorable than would be offered by a profit-maximizing
monopolist not engaged in predatory or exclusionary conduct. The failure to fulfill those specific 1996 Act duties (or
to dedicate sufficient resources to their fulfillment) may
amount to a regulatory violation without ipso facto violating
the antitrust laws.11
C. The Court Of Appeals’ Application Of “Monopoly Leveraging” Is Inconsistent With Section 2 Principles
The court of appeals’ articulation of its second theory of
Section 2 liability—monopoly leveraging—similarly countenances an antitrust violation unsupported by fundamental
antitrust principles. The phrase “monopoly leveraging” is
often employed to describe the use of power in one market to
affect competition in a second, related market. In this case,
10
As we have observed (p. 12 note 3, supra), in other contexts,
violation of extrinsic statutory or legal duties may be significant in
determining whether conduct is exclusionary for antitrust purposes.
11 Even if the 1996 Act is merely viewed as a legislative remedy to deal
with the competitive challenge posed by a monopolist’s control of the
“essential facility” of the local loop, it does not follow that a regulatory violation always amounts to an antitrust violation. Indeed, even a violation of
a court order requiring non-discriminatory access to a particular facility,
see p. 24 note 9, supra, would not without more constitute an independent
antitrust violation, even though it might be a basis for contempt.
26
the court of appeals held that a “monopoly leveraging” violation is established if a monopolist in one market uses its monopoly to “gain a competitive advantage” in a second market,
Pet. App. 30a, even if the monopolist does not have “a dangerous probability” of successfully monopolizing the second
market, id. at 31a n.13. That formulation is difficult to reconcile with the text of the Sherman Act, which proscribes
monopolization and attempted monopolization, rather than
“misuse” of market power. 3 Areeda & Hovenkamp, supra,
¶ 652a, at 89. It is also inconsistent with Spectrum Sports,
506 U.S. at 459, which clarifies that Section 2 “makes the
conduct of a single firm unlawful only when it actually
monopolizes or dangerously threatens to do so.”12
Moreover, the Second Circuit’s “monopoly leveraging”
formulation suffers from the same defect as its “essential
facilities” holding—it does not require the monopolist’s conduct to be “exclusionary” or “predatory” within the meaning
of Section 2 jurisp