An Analysis of
VaR-based Capital Requirements∗
Domenico Cuoco
The Wharton School
University of Pennsylvania
Philadelphia, PA 19104
cuoco@wharton.upenn.edu
Hong Liu
John M. Olin School of Business
Washington University in Saint Louis
St. Louis, MO 63130
liuh@olin.wustl.edu
This draft: April 2004
Abstract
We study the dynamic investment and reporting problem of a financial institution subject to capital requirements based on self-reported VaR estimates, as in the Basel Committee’s Internal Models Approach (IMA), an issue so far unexplored in the banking
literature. With constant price coefficients, we show that optimal portfolios display
a local three-fund separation property. VaR-based capital requirements induce financial institutions to tilt their portfolios towards assets with high expected return (and
high systematic risk), but result nevertheless in a decrease of the overall risk of trading
portfolios and of the probability of default. Overall, we find that capital requirements
determined on the basis of the IMA can be very effective not only in curbing portfolio
risk but also in inducing truthful revelation of this risk. A comparison with capital requirements determined according to the U.S. FED’s Pre-Commitment Approach (PCA)
is also provided.
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: D91, D92, G11, C61.
Keywords: Capital requirements, Basel Capital Accord, Internal Models Approach,
Precommitment Approach, VaR, portfolio constraints.
∗
We thank Viral Acharya, Kerry Back, Phil Dybvig, Bob Goldstein, Karel Janecek, Philippe Jorion and
seminar participants at Boston College, University of Brescia, UCLA, Carnegie Mellon, Columbia, Michigan,
HEC Montreal, Stockholm School of Economics, USI, Washington University, Wharton, the 2003 AMASES
Conference, the 2003 Blaise Pascal Conference on Financial Modeling and the 2004 AFA meeting for helpful
suggestions. The usual disclaimer applies.
An Analysis of
VaR-based Capital Requirements
Abstract
We study the dynamic investment and reporting problem of a financial institution subject to capital requirements based on self-reported VaR estimates, as in the Basel Committee’s Internal Models Approach (IMA), an issue so far unexplored in the banking
literature. With constant price coefficients, we show that optimal portfolios display
a local three-fund separation property. VaR-based capital requirements induce financial institutions to tilt their portfolios towards assets with high expected return (and
high systematic risk), but result nevertheless in a decrease of the overall risk of trading
portfolios and of the probability of default. Overall, we find that capital requirements
determined on the basis of the IMA can be very effective not only in curbing portfolio
risk but also in inducing truthful revelation of this risk. A comparison with capital requirements determined according to the U.S. FED’s Pre-Commitment Approach (PCA)
is also provided.
Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: D91, D92, G11, C61.
Keywords: Capital requirements, Basel Capital Accord, Internal Models Approach,
Precommitment Approach, VaR, portfolio constraints.
Financial institutions are required by regulators to maintain minimum levels of capital. This
regulation is normally justified as a response to the negative externalities arising from bank
failures and to the risk-shifting incentives created by deposit insurance.1 The 1988 Basel
Capital Accord imposed uniform capital requirements based on risk-adjusted assets, defined
as the sum of asset positions multiplied by asset-specific risk weights. These risk weights
were intended to reflect primarily the credit risk associated with a given asset. In 1996 the
Accord was amended to include additional minimum capital reserves to cover market risk,
defined as the risk arising from movements in the market prices of trading positions (Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision, 1996a).
The 1996 Amendment’s Internal Models Approach (IMA) determines capital requirements on the basis of the output of the financial institutions’ internal risk measurement
systems. Financial institutions are required to report daily their Value-at-Risk (VaR) at
the 99% confidence level over a one-day horizon and over a two-week horizon (ten trading
days).2 The minimum capital requirement on a given day is then equal to the sum of a
charge to cover “general market risk” and a charge to cover “credit risk” (or idiosyncratic
risk), where the market-risk charge is equal to a multiple of the average reported two-week
VaR’s in the last 60 trading days3 and the credit-risk charge is equal to 8% of risk-adjusted
assets. U.S.-regulated banks and OTC derivatives dealers are subject to capital requirements determined on the basis of the IMA.
The reliance on the financial institution’s self-reported VaRs to determine capital requirements creates an adverse selection and moral hazard problem, since the institution has
an incentive to under-report its true VaR in order to reduce capital requirements. The procedure suggested by the Basel Committee to address this problem relies on “backtesting”
(Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 1996c): regulators should evaluate on a quarterly basis the frequency of “exceptions” (that is, the frequency of daily losses exceeding the
reported VaR) for every financial institution in the most recent twelve-month period and
the multiplier used to determine the market risk charge should be increased (according to
a given scale varying between 3 and 4) if the frequency of exceptions is high.4 Additional
1
See Berger, Herring and Szegö (1995), Freixas and Santomero (2002) or Santos (2002) for a review of
the theoretical justifications for bank capital requirements.
2
Simply stated, VaR is the maximum loss of a trading portfolio over a given horizon, at a given confidence
level (i.e., a quantile of the projected profit/loss distribution at the given horizon). To avoid a duplication
of risk-measurement systems, financial institutions are allowed to derive their two-week VaR measure by
scaling up the daily VaR by the square root of ten (see: Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, 1996b,
p. 4).
3
More precisely, the market-risk charge is equal to the larger of: (i) the average reported two-week VaR’s
in the last 60 trading days times a multiplier and (ii) the last-reported two-week VaR. However, since the
multiplier is not less than 3 (see below), the average of the reported VaR’s in the last 60 trading days times
a multiplier typically exceeds the last-reported VaR.
4
The reason why backtesting is based on a daily VaR measure in spite of the fact that the market risk
charge is based on a two-week VaR measure is that VaR measures are typically computed ignoring portfolio
revisions over the VaR horizon. According to the Basel Committee, “it is often argued that value-at-risk
measures cannot be compared against actual trading outcomes, since the actual outcomes will inevitably
be ‘contaminated’ by changes in portfolio composition during the holding period. [ . . .] This argument
is persuasive with regard to the use of value-at-risk measures based on price shocks calibrated to longer
holding periods. That is, comparing the ten-day, 99th percentile risk measures from the internal models
capital requirement with actual ten-day trading outcomes would probably not be a meaningful exercise. In
particular, in any given ten day period, significant changes in portfolio composition relative to the initial
1
corrective actions in response to a high number of exceptions are left to the discretion of
regulators.
This paper studies the optimal behavior of a financial institution subject to capital requirements determined according to the IMA. We view the system of capital requirements
put in place by the 1996 Amendment as a revelation mechanism designed to induce financial
institutions to truthfully reveal the risk (VaR) of their trading portfolios and to support this
risk with adequate levels of capital, a view consistent with Rochet (1999) and Jorion (2001,
p. 65). Accordingly, we consider the simultaneous optimal choice of a reporting and investment strategy. Since the incentives to truthful revelation arise in part from the threat of
increased capital requirements in the future (through an increase in the reserve multiplier),
we consider a fully dynamic model with discrete reporting and continuous trading.
Specifically, we consider a financial institution with preferences represented by a riskaverse utility function defined over the market value of its equity capital at the end of the
planning horizon.5 We assume that the institution has fully-insured deposits and limited
liability: thus, our model allows for the risk-shifting incentives created by deposit insurance
and the option to default. The planning horizon is divided into non-overlapping “backtesting
periods”, each of which is in turn divided into non-overlapping “reporting periods”. The
institution is required to continuously maintain its capital above a minimum level, which
equals the sum of a charge to cover market risk and a charge to cover credit risk. At the
beginning of each reporting period, the institution must report to regulators its claimed VaR
as well as the actual loss over the previous period. The market-risk charge for the current
reporting period is then equal to a multiple k of the reported VaR,6 while the creditrisk charge is equal to the sum of asset positions multiplied by asset-specific credit-risk
weights.7 At the end of each backtesting period, the number of exceptions (i.e., the number
of reporting periods in which the actual loss exceeded the reported VaR) is computed and
this determines the multiple k over the next backtesting period, according to an increasing
scale.8 To capture the cost of any additional regulatory action that might be undertaken in
positions are common at major trading institutions. For this reason, the backtesting framework described
here involves the use of risk measures calibrated to a one-day holding period.” (Basel Committee on Banking
Supervision (1996c, p. 3).
5
Risk aversion on the part of financial institutions can be justified by, among other things, the value of
the institution’s charter: see Keeley (1990).
6
Consistently with empirical evidence, we find that in our model reported VaR’s display little variation
from one reporting period to the next. Thus, making capital requirements proportional to an average of
recently-reported VaR’s (rather than proportional to the last-reported VaR) would make little difference in
our results.
7
This is consistent with the Basel Capital Accord, which sets the charge to cover credit risk equal to
0.08 times the sum of asset positions multiplied by asset-specific weights ranging from 0 to 1.5 (see: Basel
Committee on Banking Supervision (2001)). This corresponds to risk weights between 0 and 0.08×1.5 = 0.12
in our definition. Unrated corporate claims (including equity) are assigned a weight of 100% (0.08 in our
definition).
8
Thus, we assume that the VaR measure used for backtesting coincides with that used to determine the
capital charge for market risk. This is without loss of generality, as any difference between the two VaR
measures can be captured by rescaling the multiplier k. For example, in our numerical calibration we take
the reporting period to be one day, as suggested by the Basel Committee, and assume that the multiplier
is determined according to the scale suggested by the Basel Committee times the square root of ten: this
adjustment captures the fact that the multiplier should be applied to a two-week (rather than one-day) VaR
(see footnote 2).
2
response to losses exceeding the reported VaR, we also allow for the possibility of pecuniary
sanctions at the end of any reporting period in which an exception is observed. These
sanctions are assumed to be proportional to the amount by which the actual loss exceeds
the reported VaR.
Therefore, the financial institution chooses the level of VaR to report in each period by
trading off the cost of higher capital requirements in the current period resulting from a
higher reported VaR against the benefit of a lower probability of pecuniary sanctions and
a lower probability of higher capital requirements in the future as a result of a loss exceeding the reported VaR. In addition, the institution simultaneously chooses a continuouslyrebalanced trading strategy for its portfolio, subject to the applicable capital requirements.
We stress that the problem we consider differs from a standard investment problem with
portfolio constraints, since capital requirements are not exogenously fixed, but vary endogenously as a result of the institution’s optimal reporting strategy.
We explicitly characterize the solution of the problem described above using martingale
duality (as in Cuoco (1997)) and parametric quadratic programming. Even with constant
price coefficients, optimal portfolios in the presence of capital requirements do not display
two-fund separation: as capital requirements become progressively more binding following
losses, financial institutions find it optimal to rebalance their portfolios in favor of assets
characterized by high risk-weight-adjusted expected returns (high systematic risks). However, we show that optimal portfolios satisfy a local three-fund separation property, with
the three funds being the riskless asset, the mean-variance efficient portfolio of risky assets
and a risk-weight-constrained minimum-variance portfolio of risky assets. For no choice of
the parameters we find VaR-based capital requirements leading to an increase in overall
portfolio risk or to a higher probability of extreme losses and default. In fact, we find that
VaR-based capital requirements are effective in completely offsetting the risk-taking incentives generated by deposit insurance and the associated default option, with the risk-taking
by a financial institution in the presence of deposit insurance and capital requirements never
exceeding that of a similar institution with unlimited liability and no capital requirements.
In general, financial institutions may optimally under-report or over-report their true
VaR’s, depending on their risk aversion, the current reserve multiplier, the number of exceptions recorded in the current backtesting period, the time remaining to the end of the
current backesting period and the level of the pecuniary penalties associated with an exception. Overall, we find that capital requirements determined on the basis of the IMA can be
very effective not only in curbing portfolio risks, but also in inducing truthful revelation of
these risks. For relative risk aversion coefficients of 0.25 or higher, the threat of a pecuniary
sanction equal to 1% of the amount by which the end-of-period loss exceeds the reported
VaR is sufficient to ensure that financial institutions never find it optimal to report VaRs
that are below true 90% VaRs.
The optimal behavior of a financial institution subject to capital requirements determined in accordance to the IMA has been so far unexplored in the banking literature.
In a static mean-variance framework, Kahane (1977) and Koehn and Santomero (1980)
showed that a more stringent capital requirement (in the form of a lower upper bound
on feasible leverage ratios) may induce financial institutions to substitute riskier assets for
less risky ones and thus may increase the risk of trading portfolios and the probability
of default. Kim and Santomero (1988) established that the same result applies to capital
3
requirements determined on the basis of risk-weighted assets, unless the risk weights happen
to be proportional to the assets’ betas. The conclusion that capital requirements could lead
to an increase in risk taking and hence in the likelihood of bank failures has been the
subject of extensive discussion in the subsequent literature.9 Furlong and Keeley (1989)
and Keeley and Furlong (1990) argued that the mean-variance framework is inappropriate
to analyze the effect of capital requirements in the presence of deposit insurance and limited
liability, because limited liability results in skewed equity return distributions. In particular,
Furlong and Keeley (1989) considered a value-maximizing financial institution and showed
that stricter leverage limits unambiguously reduce optimal risk-taking. The main reason is
that such an institution would always choose the portfolio having the maximum possible risk
under the capital requirement (i.e., a corner solution) in order to maximize the value of the
deposit insurance (a put option). Gennotte and Pyle (1991) extended the analysis of Furlong
and Keeley to allow for investment opportunities having non-zero net present value (NPV)
and showed that in this setting tighter capital restrictions can lead financial institutions
to increase asset risk. However, this result was obtained under the key assumption that
the institution finds it optimal to invest in risky assets having negative NPV: thus, as
long as the institution has access to traded securities (zero-NPV investments) with the
same or higher risk, the result in Furlong and Keeley would still hold. While all of the
above studies considered a static setting, Blum (1999) used a two-period model to show
that the incentives to increase the risk of trading portfolios in response to tighter capital
requirements are even higher in a dynamic setting. This is because capital requirements
increase the marginal utility of a unit of capital tomorrow and thus can lead to an increase
in risk in an effort to increase expected return. Differently from these papers, we take into
account the impact of capital requirement on the risk-shifting incentives created by deposit
insurance and limited liability in a dynamic setting with continuous trading and hence with
portfolio return distributions that are not restricted to be normals or truncated normals. In
addition, we allow for more general capital requirements that include a charge for market
risk in addition to that based on risk-weighted assets. While asset substitution incentives
are present in our model, we find that capital requirements never have perverse effects on
risk-taking or on the probability of failure. Moreover, differently from Furlong and Keeley
(1989), this lack of perverse effects is not due to the fact that the financial institution acts
as a risk-lover and is always at a corner solution.
Sentana (2001), Emmer, Klüppelberg and Korn (2001), Vorst (2001), Basak and Shapiro
(2001) and Cuoco, He and Issaenko (2002) considered the investment problem of a trader
subject to an exogenous limit on the VaR of the trading portfolio. None of these papers incorporates limited liability or a realistic model of capital requirements. The first four papers
considered the case of a fixed VaR limit, which does not capture the constraint imposed by
capital requirements on financial institutions. Cuoco, He and Issaenko considered the case
in which the limit varies as a function of the value of the trading portfolio. Their results for
the proportional case imply that if the VaR of a financial institution’s trading portfolio were
perfectly and continuously observable by regulators and minimum capital requirements at
any given point in time were simply equal to a fixed multiple of the contemporaneous VaR
(with no penalties for observed exceptions), then, under the assumption of CRRA pref9
See Jackson (1999) for a review of the related empirical evidence.
4
erences and unlimited liability, the optimal portfolio for a financial institution subject to
capital requirements would involve a constant proportional allocation to the mean-variance
efficient portfolio. Moreover, the capital requirement would either always bind or never
bind. Neither of these conclusions holds for the more realistic model of capital regulation
considered in this paper.10
Again in a static setting, Chan, Greenbaum and Thakor (1992) and Giammarino, Lewis
and Sappington (1993) studied the optimal design of a mechanism that induces truthful risk
revelation in a setting in which regulators also provide deposit insurance. By contrast, our
focus is not on mechanism design but on the analysis of the specific mechanism implemented
by the 1996 Amendment. Ju and Pearson (1999) examined, in a static setting, the bias
that arises when the VaR of a portfolio is determined on the basis of the delta-normal
method with variances and covariances estimated using past data: in this case, a trader
subject to a binding VaR constraint and possessing private information about the relation
between current variances and covariances and historical ones, is able to select portfolios
whose true VaR exceeds the estimated VaR and hence to assume risks in excess of the
stated limit. Ju and Pearson quantified the extent of this bias assuming that the supervisor
monitoring the limit provides no incentives for the trader to reveal his information and
that the trader has one of three objectives: maximizing the portfolio VaR, maximizing
the portfolio expected return, or minimizing the variance of the difference between the
return of the chosen portfolio and the return of an exogenously-given reference portfolio.
By contrast, because of the penalties associated with exceptions, the 1996 Amendment does
provide incentives to financial institutions to reveal private information about risk: these
incentives (in addition to a more realistic investment objective) are important features of
the model we consider.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section I describes our model in detail.
Section II characterizes optimal trading strategies in the absence of capital requirements.
Section III describes our solution approach to the joint reporting and investment problem
in the presence of capital requirements and provides some explicit characterization of optimal trading strategies in this section. Section IV provides a numerical analysis. Section
V concludes. Appendix A examines capital requirements determined on the basis of the
Pre-Commitment Approach (PCA), an alternative approach proposed by the U.S. Federal
Reserve Bank.11 Appendix B contains all the proofs. Appendix C provides some additional
auxiliary results.
1
The Model
We consider a financial institution with a planning horizon equal to T backtesting periods,
where T is a positive integer. Without loss of generality, we normalize the length of a
backtesting period to 1. Each backtesting period comprises n non-overlapping reporting
10
Leippold, Trojani and Vanini (2001), using asymptotic approximation techniques, extended the analysis
of an exogenous proportional VaR limit in Cuoco, He and Issaenko to incorporate stochastically-varying
price coefficients and also examine the equilibrium implications of such a limit.
11
As will be shown in Appendix A, PCA-based capital requirements are a special case of the model of
capital requirements studied in Section III. In related work, Kupiec and O’Brien (1997) provide an analysis
of PCA-based capital requirements in a static setting.
5
periods of equal length τ = 1/n. At the beginning of each reporting period, the financial
institution is required to report to a regulator its current VaR as well as the actual profit/loss
over the previous reporting period. As explained later, the reported VaR determines the
capital charge to cover market risk for the period.
The financial institution has liabilities represented by deposits and (equity) capital. For
simplicity, we assume that the face value of deposits D is fixed over the planning horizon
and that there are no equity issues or dividend payments over this period. Deposits are fully
insured and earn the risk-free interest rate, which is paid out continuously to depositors.
The market value of deposits is therefore constant and equal to D.
The investment opportunities are represented by m + 1 long-lived assets. The first asset
is riskless and earns a constant continuously-compounded interest rate r ≥ 0. The other
m assets are risky and their price process S (inclusive of reinvested dividends) follows a
geometric Brownian motion with drift vector r1̄ + µ and diffusion matrix σ, i.e.,
Z
S(t) = S(0) +
t
Z
S
I (s)(r1̄ + µ) ds +
0
t
I S (s)σ dw(s),
0
where I S (t) denotes the m × m diagonal matrix with elements S(t), 1̄ = (1, . . . , 1)> and w is
an m-dimensional Brownian motion. We assume without loss of generality that σ has rank
m.12 The financial institution can trade continuously and without frictions over [0, T ].13,14
Letting θ be the m-dimensional stochastic process representing the (dollar) investment
in the risky assets, the evolution of the value A of the institution’s asset portfolio over any
reporting period is then given by
dA(t) = (A(t)r + θ(t)> µ) dt + θ(t)> σ dw(t) − rD dt,
(1)
where the last term reflects interest payments to depositors.
We define the institution’s regulatory capital K = A − D as the difference between the
value of the institution’s asset portfolio and the value of the institution’s deposits.15 Since
12
If d = rank(σ) < m, some stocks are redundant and can be omitted from the analysis. Moreover, w can
be redefined in this case to be a d-dimensional Brownian motion.
13
The assumption of continuous frictionless trading is of course a simplification in the case of a financial
institution for which loans constitute a significant portion of investments. However, incorporating illiquidity
into the present model would significantly add to its complexity. We view the frictionless case as a reasonable
starting point for a first analysis of VaR-based capital requirements, especially in view of the increasing use
of loan securitization by financial institutions.
14
While we do not explicitly impose short-sale constraints, our results would be unchanged by these
constraints. As it will be shown in Proposition 6, capital requirements never induce financial institutions to
short (long) assets that are held long (short) in the unconstrained mean-variance efficient (MVE) portfolio.
Thus, assets that are held short in the unconstrained MVE portfolio would never be held in the presence of
short-sale constraints (with or without capital requirements) and thus can simply be ignored. On the other
hand, assets that are held long in the unconstrained MVE portfolio are also held in non-negative amounts
in the presence of capital requirements and thus are unaffected by short-sale constraints.
15
Our definition of regulatory capital is different from the market value of the institution’s equity because, consistently with practice, the market value of deposit insurance is not included in the value of the
institution’s assets. Thus, at the terminal date T , the market value of the institution’s equity is equal to
K(T )+ = max[0, K(T )]. As it will become clear from equations (2) and (3), we assume that capital requirements are defined in terms of regulatory capital, but that the institution has preferences defined in terms of
the market value of capital.
6
the market value of deposits is fixed and there are no new equity issues, it follows from
equation (1) that the institution’s regulatory capital satisfies
dK(t) = (K(t)r + θ(t)> µ) dt + θ(t)> σ dw(t).
The financial institution is required to maintain at all times its regulatory capital above
a minimum level equal to the sum of the charge to cover general market risk plus a charge to
cover credit (or idiosyncratic) risk. The capital charge to cover market risk equals the VaR
reported at the beginning of the current reporting period times a multiplier k. The capital
charge to cover credit risk equals the sum of the institution’s trading positions (long and
short) multiplied by asset-specific risk weights. Thus, letting β ∈ [0, 1]m denote the vector of
asset risk weights,16 the capital charge to cover credit risk at time t equals β > (θ(t)+ +θ(t)− ),
where for any x ∈ IR x+ = max[0, x] and x− = max[0, −x].17 Hence, if VaR ≥ 0 denotes
the VaR reported to regulators at the beginning of the current reporting period and k is
the currently-applicable multiplier, the institution must satisfy the constraint
K(t) ≥ kVaR + β > (θ(t)+ + θ(t)− )
(2)
at all times during the reporting period.18
The institution is subject to pecuniary sanctions at the end of each reporting period in
which the actual loss exceeds the reported VaR.19 We assume that the sanction is proportional to the amount by which the actual loss exceeds the VaR and denote the proportionality coefficient by λ, where λ ≥ 0. At the end of each backtesting period, the number i
(i = 0, 1, . . . , n) of reporting periods in which the actual loss exceeded the reported VaR is
computed, and the capital reserve multiplier k for the next backtesting period is set equal
to k(i), for some given positive numbers k(0) ≤ k(1) ≤ . . . ≤ k(n).
We assume that the financial institution’s trading strategy, and hence the financial
institution’s true VaR, are unobservable by the regulator. Therefore, the reported VaR
can differ from the true VaR. However, the threat of pecuniary sanctions at the end of
each reporting period and the revision of the capital reserve multiplier k at the end of
each backtesting period represent incentives to not under-report the VaR, while the capital
requirement provides an incentive to not over-report.
The financial institution has limited liability and preferences represented by a power
HARA utility function over the market value of its capital at the end of the planning
horizon. Thus, it chooses a reporting and trading strategy over [0, T ] so as to maximize
E [u (K(T ))] ,
16
It is a straightforward extension to allow β to be different also across long and short positions.
Consistently with existing regulation, we are implicitly assuming a zero risk weight for investment in
the money market account.
18
The constraint K(t) ≥ β > (θ(t)+ +θ(t)− ) is identical to the one that would arise in the presence of margin
requirements if the trader were allowed to earn market interest on the margin: see Cuoco and Liu (2000).
Thus, while we assume that trading is frictionless, margin requirements could be easily accommodated and
would amount to an increase in the vector of risk weights β by an amount equal to the proportional margin
requirement.
19
These sanctions are meant to capture reputation costs or additional disciplinary actions that might be
undertaken by regulators. The threat of these sanctions is necessary for institutions to optimally report
non-zero VaRs.
17
7
where
u(K) =
(K + + ε)1−γ
1−γ
(3)
for some ε ≥ 0 and γ > 0, γ 6= 1.20
2
The Unconstrained Problem
We start by deriving an analytical solution for the investment problem of a financial institution not subject to capital requirements:
h
V U (K, t) = max E u (K(T ))
θ
K(t) = K
i
(4)
s.t. dK(s) = (K(s)r + θ(s)> µ) ds + θ(s)> σ dw(s)
K(s) ≥ −D for all s ∈ [t, T ].
The constraint K ≥ −D reflects the fact that the value of the financial institution’s
assets, which equals D + K, cannot be negative. We refer to the problem in (4) as the
unconstrained problem. To simplify comparison with the next section,which deals with the
constrained problem with capital requirements, we use a martingale duality approach to
solve the above problem.
Letting
!
!
|κ|2
>
ξ(t) = exp − r +
t − κ w(t)
(5)
2
denote the state-price density process, where
κ = σ −1 µ,
it follows from Cox and Huang (1989), Pliska (1986) or Karatzas, Lehoczky and Shreve (1987)
that the problem in (4) can be equivalently written as the static problem
V U (K, t) = min max Et [u(x) − ψ (ξ(T )x − ξ(t)K)] ,
ψ≥0 x≥−D
(6)
where ψ is a Lagrangian multiplier. Setting Z = ψξ, it then follows from (5) that
dZ(t) = −Z(t) (r dt + κ> dw(t))
and (6) implies
h
i
V U (K, t) = min Ṽ U (z, t) + zK ,
z≥0
where
h
Ṽ U (z, t) = E ṽ U (Z(T )) | Z(t) = z
i
(7)
and
ṽ U (z) = max [u(x) − zx].
x≥−D
(8)
The next proposition describes the solution of the maximization problem in (8). For
convenience, let b = 1 − 1/γ.
20
The case γ = 1 can be treated similarly.
8
Lemma 1 If u(0) > −∞ (that is, if either ε > 0 or γ < 1), there exists a unique zU ∈
(0, ε−γ ] satisfying
zb
ε1−γ
− U + (ε − D)zU −
= 0.
(9)
b
1−γ
Lemma 2 Let zU be the constant in Lemma 1 if u(0) > −∞ and let zU = +∞ otherwise.
Then the solution of the maximization problem in (8) is given by K = f U (z), where
(
U
f (z) =
z
− γ1
−ε
if z ≤ zU
−D
Hence
U
U
(10)
otherwise.
U
ṽ (z) = u(f (z)) − zf (z) =
−
zb
b
ε1−γ
1−γ
+ εz
if z ≤ zU
+ Dz
otherwise.
(11)
f U (z)
The function
in (10) is decreasing for z ∈ (0, +∞) and strictly positive and strictly
decreasing for z ∈ (0, zU ), with a single discontinuity at z = zU . The function ṽ U (z) in (11)
is continuous and convex.
The result in Lemma 2 allows the derivation of an explicit expression for the dual value
function in (7) and for the optimal trading strategy.
Proposition 1 The dual value function Ṽ U in (7) is given by
Ṽ U (z, t)
=
−
z b −b(r+ 12 (1−b)κ2 )(T −t)
N
b e
+ εze−r(T −t) N
+
ε1−γ
1−γ N
−
log(
log(
zU
z
log(
zU
z
)+(r+√
( 21 −b)|κ|2 )(T −t)
|κ| T −t
r− 12 |κ|2
√
)+(
)(T −t)
|κ| T −t
zU
z
1
|κ|2 )(T −t)
)+(r+
√ 2
(12)
|κ| T −t
+ Dze−r(T −t) N −
log(
zU
z
1
|κ|2 )(T −t)
)+(r−
√ 2
|κ| T −t
,
where N is the standard normal distribution function. In particular, Ṽ U is strictly convex
in z for all t ∈ [0, T ).
Proposition 2 The optimal trading strategy θU for the unconstrained problem in (4) is
given by θ(t) = θU (Z(t), t), where
−1
U
θU (z, t) = z Ṽzz
(z, t) (σσ > )
µ.
(13)
Moreover, under the optimal investment policy, the financial institution’s capital at time t
is given by K(t) = K U (Z(t), t), where
K U (z, t) = −ṼzU (Z(t), t).
In particular,
K U (T ) = f U (Z(T )),
where f U is the function in (10).
9
Portfolio weight (θU /(D + K U ))
10
t=1
8
t=0
6
4
2
0
0.01
0.1
1
10
100
U
Asset value (D + K )
Figure 1:
The graph plots the optimal portfolio allocation to stocks in the unconstrained model
at t = 0 and t = 1 as a function of asset value, for the case γ = .25, ε = 0, T = 2, r = .01, κ = .27,
σ = .22 and D = 1.
Corollary 1 We have
lim θU (z, t) =
z→0
1
−1
(σσ > ) µK U (z, t),
γ
lim θU (z, t) = 0,
z→+∞
lim K U (z, t) = +∞,
z→0
(
lim K U (z, t) =
z→+∞
− e−r(T −t) D
if u(0) > −∞,
0
otherwise.
Proposition 2 implies that, in the absence of capital requirements, the financial institutions has incentives to exploit the option to default by choosing a discontinuous distribution
of capital at the terminal date. As long as the state variable Z(T ) is lower than zU , terminal
−1
capital equals Z(T ) γ − ε > 0 and default is avoided. However, in states in which Z(T )
is higher than zU , terminal capital equals − D: in other words, the institution completely
depletes its assets and defaults for the largest possible amount. This is true even in the
case ε = 0 as long as the utility function is finite at zero (that is, as long as γ < 1): infinite
marginal utility at zero is not sufficient to prevent default if the institution can default for
a non-infinitesimal amount.
The incentives to exploit the default option are also evident in Figure 1, which plots the
optimal portfolio weight θU /(D + K U ) as a function of asset value at two different points
in time (t = 0 and t = 1) for the case γ = .25, ε = 0, T = 2, r = .01, κ = .27, σ = .22
and D = 1.21 As asset value decreases below the default point e−r(T −t) D, the proportional
21
The figure plots asset value on a logarithmic scale, since the portfolio weight decreases steeply to zero
as asset value approaches zero.
10
allocation to risky assets in the absence of capital requirements increases significantly and
would become unboundedly large as the end of the investment horizon approaches.
3
The Constrained Problem
3.1
Recursion for the Value Function
Turning next to the institution’s investment and reporting problem in the presence of capital
requirement, let V (K, K − , VaR, i, k, t) denote the value function for the institution’s problem at time t conditional on current capital being K, capital at the beginning of the current
reporting period being K − , the VaR reported at the beginning of the current reporting
period being VaR, the number of exceptions in the current reporting period being i and the
current capital reserve multiplier being k. Without loss of generality, suppose that t is in
the h-th reporting period, i.e., that t ∈ [(h − 1)τ, hτ ). Finally, let T = {1, 2, . . . , T } denote
the set of backtesting dates. Then it follows from the principle of dynamic programming
that
h
V (K, K − , VaR, i, k, t) = max E v(K(hτ ), K − , VaR, i, k, hτ )
θ
K(t) = K
i
(14)
dK(s) = (K(s)r + θ(s)> µ) ds + θ(s)> σ dw(s),
s.t.
K(s) ≥ kVaR + β > (θ(s)+ + θ(s)− )
for all s ∈ [t, hτ ),
for K ≥ kVaR, where
v(K, K − , VaR, i, k, hτ )
=
(15)
max V (K1 , K1 , VaR1 , i1 , k1 , hτ )1{K≥K − −VaR}
VaR1 ≥0
+ max V (K2 , K2 , VaR2 , i2 , k2 , hτ )1{K 0, then
h
V (K, K − , VaR, i, k, t) = min Ṽ (ψ, K − , VaR, i, k, t) + ψK
ψ>0
i
(20)
for all K ≥ kVaR and all t ∈ [(h − 1)τ, hτ ), where
Ṽ (z, K − , VaR, i, k, t)
(21)
= min E ṽ(Zν (τ ), K − , VaR, i, k, hτ )
ν∈N
− kVaR
Z
hτ
Zν (s)ν0 (s) ds
Zν (t) = z
t
s.t. dZν (t) = −Zν (t) (r + ν0 (t)) dt + κν (t)> dw(t) .
While in the unconstrained case it was possible to directly compute the dual value
function Ṽ U , an analytic solution is not available in the constrained case. However, the
dual value function Ṽ can be computed numerically by solving the associated HamiltonJacobi-Bellman (HJB) equation. Below we denote by ιi the i-th column of the m × m
identity matrix.
13
Proposition 4 If β ∈ IRm
++ the dual value function Ṽ in (21) is strictly decreasing and
strictly convex in z for all t ∈ [(h − 1)τ, hτ ) and it solves the HJB equation
"
1
Ṽz + kVaR
0 = Ṽt − rz Ṽz + z 2 Ṽzz min |σ −1 (µ + ν− − ν0 1̄)|2 −
ν0
z Ṽzz
ν∈Ã 2
#
(22)
with terminal condition
Ṽ (z, K − , VaR, i, k, hτ ) = ṽ(z, K − , VaR, i, k, hτ ).
Moreover, the process ν ∗ attaining the minimum in (22) satisfies
0 ≤ ν0∗ ≤ M
and
M (1̄ − β) ≤ ν− ≤ M (1̄ + β),
>
∗
where M = max{|ι>
i µ|/ιi β : i = 1, . . . , m}. Hence, ν ∈ N .
Remark 3 The terminal condition for Ṽ in Proposition 4 is given by the function ṽ defined in (19). An explicit expression for ṽ(z, K − , VaR, i, k, hτ ) in terms of the initial value
Ṽ (z, K − , VaR, i, k, hτ ) of the dual value function computed over the next reporting period
[hτ, (h + 1)τ ) is provided in Appendix C. This expression simplifies the recursive solution of
the dual value function.
3.3
Optimal Investment Strategy
Once the dual value function Ṽ is known, the optimal trading strategy θ and the process
for the institution’s capital K can be recovered as in Proposition 2. To prevent excessively
cumbersome notation, we suppress from now on the dependence of the dual value function
on the variables (K − , VaR, i, k) which are constant within each reporting period.
Proposition 5 If β ∈ IRm
++ , the optimal trading strategy θ for the constrained problem
in (14) is given by θ(t) = θ(Zν ∗ (t), t), where
∗
θ(z, t) = z Ṽzz (z, t)(σσ > )−1 (µ + ν−
(z, t) − ν0∗ (z, t)1̄).
(23)
Moreover, under the optimal trading strategy, the institution’s capital at time t is given by
K(t) = K(Zν ∗ (t), t), where
K(z, t) = −Ṽz (z, t).
(24)
In particular, K(z, hτ ) = f (z), where f is the function defined in Appendix C.
A comparison of equations (13) and (23) shows that the constrained optimal trading
strategy coincides with the unconstrained optimal trading strategy in a fictitious economy
∗ − ν ∗ 1̄. The next proposition proin which the vector of stock risk premia equals µ + ν−
0
vides an explicit characterization of the optimal trading strategy in the presence of capital
requirements. We denote by Ii the i × m matrix consisting of the first i rows of the m × m
identity matrix.
14
Proposition 6 Suppose that β ∈ IRm
++ and that all the components of the unconstrained
> −1
mean-variance efficient portfolio (σσ ) µ are different from zero.23 For i, j ∈ {1, 2, . . . , m},
j ≤ i, let
>
> > −1
ι>
j HIi (Ii σσ Ii ) Ii µ
ηi,j = > >
,
ιj HIi (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii Hβ
where
H = diag sign (σσ > )−1 µ
and suppose without loss of generality that the assets are sorted so that
n
o
ηi,i = min ηi,j : ηi,j > 0, j = 1, . . . , i .
For i = 1, 2, . . . , m, let
hi = β > HIi> (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii (µ − ηi,i Hβ)
and let
hm+1 = β > H(σσ > )−1 µ.
Then
0 = h1 ≤ h2 ≤ . . . ≤ hm+1 .
If
−
Ṽz (z, t) + kVaR
≥ hm+1 ,
z Ṽzz (z, t)
then ν0∗ (z, t) = 0 and
θ(z, t) = z Ṽzz (z, t)(σσ > )−1 µ
(25)
If
hi ≤ −
Ṽz (z, t) + kVaR
< hi+1 ,
z Ṽzz (z, t)
for i = 1, 2, . . . , m then
ν0∗ (z, t)
=
β > HIi> (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii µ +
Ṽz (z,t)+kVaR
z Ṽzz (z,t)
(26)
β > HIi> (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii Hβ
and
θ(z, t) = z Ṽzz (z, t)Ii> (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii µ − ν0∗ (z, t)Hβ ,
(27)
In particular, Hθ ≥ 0, that is, the components of the constrained optimal portfolio never
have the opposite sign of the corresponding components of the mean-variance efficient portfolio.
23
If an asset is not included in the unconstrained mean-variance efficient portfolio, it would not be included
in the constrained portfolio and thus can be ignored.
15
The fact that the components of the constrained optimal portfolio never have the opposite sign of the corresponding components of the mean-variance efficient portfolio implies
that the nonlinear portfolio constraint in (14) is equivalent to the pair of linear constraints
Hθ(s) ≥ 0
>
K(s) ≥ kVaR + β Hθ(s).
(28)
(29)
The characterization of the optimal portfolio strategy in the previous Proposition is then
quite intuitive: as long as the non-negativity constraint in (28) is not binding, constrained
optimal portfolios are combinations of the portfolio that maximizes expected return for
a given variance (the mean-variance efficient portfolio) and the portfolio that minimizes
the charge for credit risk β > Hθ for a given variance: we refer to the latter portfolio as
the constrained minimum-variance portfolio, since it is also the portfolio that minimizes
variance subject to a constraint on the charge for credit risk. More generally, for hi <
− Ṽz (z,t)+kVaR
≤ hi+1 the non-negativity constraint in (28) binds for the last m − i assets,
z Ṽ (z,t)
zz
so that ι>
j θ(z, t) = 0 for j = m − i, . . . , m and (as shown in equation (27))
θ(z, t) = z Ṽzz (z, t)πiMVE − z Ṽzz (z, t)ν0∗ (z, t)πiCMV ,
where
πiMVE = (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii µ
denotes the mean-variance efficient portfolio of the first i risky assets and
πiCMV = (Ii σσ > Ii> )−1 Ii Hβ
denotes the constrained minimum-variance portfolio of the first i risky assets.
Both h(z, t) = − Ṽz (z,t)+kVaR
and K(z, t) = −Ṽz (z, t) are monotonically decreasing funcz Ṽ (z,t)
zz
tions of z.24 Thus, Proposition 6 shows that when capital K(Zν ∗ (t), t) is large (that
is, when Zν ∗ (t) is small and h(Zν ∗ (t), t) ≥ hm+1 ), the capital constraint does not bind
(ν0∗ (Zν ∗ (t), t) = 0) and the financial institution holds the mean-variance efficient portfolio
MVE
. For lower levels of capital (that is, when h(Zν ∗ (t), t) < hm+1 ), the
of risky assets πm
constraint starts to bind (ν0∗ (Zν ∗ (t), t) becomes positive) and the institution is forced to
alter its leverage to satisfy the constraint. At the same time, it finds it optimal to rebalance its portfolio of risky assets: this rebalancing is done by shorting the constrained
CMV
minimum-variance portfolio πm
.
For lower levels of capital (higher values of Zν ∗ (t)), shorting of the corrective portfolio
progressively increases, until the institution reaches a point where its investment in the mth asset is zero (this happens when h(Zν ∗ (t), t) = hm ). Beyond this point, the institution
simply drops the m-th asset from its portfolio, since it is never optimal to short (respectively,
long) an asset that is held in positive (respectively, negative) amounts in the unconstrained
mean-variance efficient portfolio. If the assets are uncorrelated (σ is diagonal) the m-th
>
asset is the one with the lowest ratio of absolute risk premium |ι>
j µ| to risk weight ιj β.
The term ν0∗ can be interpreted as the Lagrangian multiplier on the constraint in the primal problem (14):
thus ν0∗ is inversely related to capital K. Since h is a decreasing function of ν0∗ (as shown in equation (26)),
h must be an increasing function of K (that is, a decreasing function of z).
24
16
Thus, as the institution is forced to reduce its allocation to risky assets to satisfy the
capital constraint, it finds it optimal to tilt its portfolio toward assets with high absolute
risk premia and low risk weights.25 If the assets are correlated, then correlations are also
taken into account in deciding which asset is dropped first from the portfolio, and the m-th
asset is the one with the lowest ratio ηm,j .
If capital decreases (Zν ∗ (t) increases) even further and the constraint becomes even more
severe, the institution sequentially drops other risky assets from its portfolio, concentrating
on those characterized by progressively higher absolute risk premia and lower risk weights.
This happens each time that h(Zν ∗ (t), t) exceeds a new value hj . Eventually, if h(Zν ∗ (t), t) =
h1 = 0 (that is, if K(Zν ∗ (t), t) = kVaR), the institution is forced to invest its entire portfolio
in the riskless asset. In general, whenever h(Zν ∗ (t), t) is between hi and hi+1 , the institution
only holds the first i risky assets and its portfolio is a combination of the riskless asset and
two funds of risky assets: the mean-variance efficient portfolio of the first i assets, πiMVE and
the constrained minimum-variance portfolio of the first i assets, πiCMV . Thus, locally (that
is, between any pair hi and hi+1 ), optimal portfolios satisfy three-fund separation.
3.4
The One-Dimensional Case
Not surprisingly, the results in the previous two subsections take a very simple form in the
case of a single risky asset, as shown in the following Corollary.
Corollary 2 In the case of a single risky asset (m = 1) and a positive risk premium (µ > 0)
the HJB equation (22) reduces to
"
2
2
µ
σ
0 = Ṽt − rz Ṽz + z Ṽzz min
µ
,−
β
2 2
1
µ
− z 2 Ṽzz min
2
σ
,
σ
β
Ṽz + kVaR
z Ṽzz (z, t)
Ṽz + kVaR
z Ṽzz (z, t)
!#
!2
.
Moreover, the optimal investment strategy in (23) reduces to
µ 1
, (K(z, t) − kVaR)
σ2 β
1
µ
1
= min
K(z, t), (K(z, t) − kVaR) ,
Γ(z, t) σ 2
β
θ(z, t) = min z Ṽzz (z, t)
(30)
where
Γ(z, t) = −
Ṽz (z, t)
z Ṽzz (z, t)
is the primal value function relative risk aversion coefficient.26
25
This substitution effect is similar to the one described by Kohen and Santomero (1980), Kim and
Santomero (1988) and Rochet (1992) in a static setting and by Blum (1999) in a two-period setting.
26
By duality,
z = VK (K(z, t), t) = VK (−Ṽz (z, t), t)
17
4
Analysis of Optimal Policies
For our numerical analysis, we fix throughout the backtesting period to one year, the investment horizon to two years (T = 2) and the reporting period to one day (n = 250,
τ = 1/250) and we assume that the reserve multiplier over the second year is determined
according to the schedule proposed by the Basel Committee multiplied by the square root
of ten,27 that is,
√
if i ≤ 4
3.00√10 = 9.49
3.40 10 = 10.75
if i = 5
√
if i = 6
3.50√10 = 11.07
k(i) = 3.65 10 = 11.54
if i = 7
√
3.75√10 = 11.86
if i = 8
3.85
10
=
12.17
if i = 9
√
4.00 10 = 12.65
if i ≥ 10.
We consider the cases in which the number m of risky assets equals 1 or 2.28 In either
case, we set r = 0 and choose the vector of risk premia µ and the volatility matrix σ so
that the risk premium (respectively, the volatility) of the mean-variance efficient portfolio
of risky assets equals 0.059 (respectively, 0.22).29 In the case of two risky assets, we assume
in addition that the volatility of the first asset (respectively, the second asset) is 25% higher
(respectively, 25% lower) than the volatility of the mean-variance efficient portfolio and that
the correlation coefficients between the returns on the two assets is 0.50.30
We solve for the dual value function recursively as explained in the previous section by
numerically integrating the PDE (22) using the method of lines.31 We also compute the
distribution function P of the state variable Zν ∗ at the end of each reporting period by
using the method of lines to solve the PDE
∂
1 ∂
P (z, t) =
|κν ∗ (z, t)z|2 Pz (z, t) + r + ν0∗ (z, t) zPz (z, t),
∂t
2 ∂z
P (z, (h − 1)τ ) = 1{z≥ψ∗ } ,
(31)
and hence (differentiating with respect to z and rearranging)
−
Ṽz (z, t)
K(z, t)VKK (K(z, t), t)
=−
.
VK (K(z, t), t)
z Ṽzz (z, t)
27
See footnote 8.
As noted at the end of the previous section, optimal investment policies satisfy local three-fund separation, so that considering additional risky assets would not affect the analysis.
29
These values correspond to the mean risk premium and the return standard deviation of the market
portfolio as estimated by Ibbotson and
Sinquefeld
(1982).
.07225
.27500 .00000
30
These assumptions imply that µ =
and σ =
in our simulations with
.02937
.08250 .14289
m = 2.
31
The method of lines discretizes the spatial variable z and replaces partial derivatives with finite differences to generate a system of first-order ODE’s in the time variable that can be solved backward starting
from the terminal condition.
28
18
for t ∈ [(h−1)τ, hτ ), where ψ ∗ is the value of ψ solving (20) with t = (h−1)τ .32 This allows
us to compute the distribution of the financial institution’s capital using equation (24), and
hence the true VaR of the portfolio, which we compare to the reported VaR. For comparison
purposes, we also compute the optimal policies and the true VaR for the unconstrained
problem described in Section 2.
4.1
One Risky Asset
Table 1 shows the optimal reporting and investment strategy at the beginning of the first
and of the last reporting period in the first year (t = 0 and t = 249/250 = .996, respectively)
for three different values of the number violations in the current backtesting period (i = 0,
i = 5 and i = 9), two different values of the current reserve multiplier (k = 9.49 and
k = 12.65) and three different values of the current leverage ratio LR = D/(D + K),33 for
the case γ = .25, ε = 0, β = .08,34 λ = .01 and m = 1. For each combination of (t, i, k, LR),
the table shows the reported VaR normalized by the total asset value v = VaR/(D + K),
the coefficient of relative risk aversion of the primal value function Γ = −KVKK /VK ,
the maximum possible proportional allocation to risky assets under the capital requirent
constraint π̄ = (1 − LR − kv)/β,35 the proportional allocation to risky assets π = θ/(D + K)
and the true 1-day 90% and 99% VaRs normalized by the total asset value v.90 and v.99 .
For comparison purposes, the table also shows the relative risk aversion coefficient ΓU , the
proportional allocation to risky assets π U and the true normalized 1-day 90% and 99% VaRs
U and v U in the unconstrained case. Table 2 shows the same information for a higher
v.90
.99
value of the institution’s risk aversion coefficient (γ = .50).
For the set of parameters considered in Table 1, the proportional allocation to risky
assets in the absence of capital requirements varies between 482.7% and 820.2%, increasing
when the leverage ratio increases (asset value decreases) and the option to default becomes
more valuable (as shown in Figure 1). Capital requirements are effective in curbing the
risk of trading portfolios, reducing the range of the proportional allocation to risky assets
to between 18.2% and 412.2%. Not surprisingly, this risk reduction is larger when capital
requirements are more stringent (that is, when the reserve multiplier k is larger). Moreover,
the allocation to risky assets becomes inversely related to leverage ratios, since as capital
falls and leverage ratios increase, financial institutions are forced to liquidate their holdings
of risky assets to avoid violating capital requirements. As a result of this dynamic behavior,
the range of true 99% daily VaRs falls from between 14.60% and 24.15% in the unconstrained
32
The PDE in (31) is obtained by integrating the forward Kolmogorov equation
∂
∂
1 ∂2
p(z, t) =
|κν ∗ (z, t)z|2 p(z, t) +
2
∂t
2 ∂z
∂z
(r + ν0∗ (z, t))zp(z, t)
solved by the density function p(z, t) = Pz (z, t).
33
The exact values of the three leverage ratios used for all the tables in the paper are 1/(1 + e3 ) = .0474,
1/(1 + e0 ) = .5000 and 1/(1 + e−3 ) = .9526 before rounding.
34
See footnote 7.
35
The constraint in (14) implies
θ
K − kVaR
1 − LR − kv
≤
=
.
D+K
β(D + K)
β
19
Parameter values: γ = .25, ε = 0, β = .08, λ = .01, τ = .004, m = 1
t
i
k
LR
v
Γ
π̄
π
v.90
v.99
ΓU
πU
U
v.90
U
v.99
0
0
0
0
0
0
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0663
.0348
.0033
.2862
.2862
.2862
4.243
4.243
4.243
4.041
2.121
0.201
.0663
.0348
.0033
.0663
.0348
.0033
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
0
0
0
0
0
0
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0515
.0270
.0026
.3133
.3133
.3133
3.952
3.952
3.952
3.707
1.945
0.185
.0515
.0270
.0026
.0515
.0270
.0026
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
0
0
0
5
5
5
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0667
.0350
.0033
.2920
.2921
.2921
4.197
4.197
4.197
3.976
2.087
0.198
.0667
.0350
.0033
.0667
.0350
.0033
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
0
0
0
5
5
5
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0505
.0265
.0025
.2914
.2914
.2914
4.126
4.126
4.126
3.930
2.063
0.196
.0505
.0265
.0025
.0977
.0516
.0049
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
0
0
0
10
10
10
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0656
.0345
.0033
.2781
.2781
.2781
4.327
4.327
4.327
4.122
2.164
0.205
.0656
.0345
.0033
.1012
.0534
.0050
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
0
0
0
10
10
10
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0504
.0265
.0025
.2913
.2914
.2914
4.127
4.127
4.127
3.931
2.063
0.196
.0504
.0265
.0025
.0976
.0513
.0049
.2357
.0991
.0086
4.927
6.148
6.698
.0853
.1062
.1155
.1488
.1842
.1994
.996
.996
.996
0
0
0
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0656
.0345
.0033
.2781
.2781
.2781
4.327
4.327
4.327
4.122
2.164
0.205
.0656
.0345
.0033
.1016
.0533
.0050
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
.996
.996
.996
0
0
0
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0504
.0265
.0025
.2913
.2914
.2914
4.127
4.127
4.127
3.931
2.063
0.196
.0504
.0265
.0025
.0860
.0452
.0043
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
.996
.996
.996
5
5
5
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0667
.0350
.0033
.2915
.2915
.2915
4.202
4.202
4.202
3.984
2.091
0.198
.0667
.0350
.0033
.0667
.0350
.0033
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
.996
.996
.996
5
5
5
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0517
.0271
.0026
.3171
.3172
.3172
3.923
3.923
3.923
3.662
1.922
0.182
.0517
.0271
.0026
.0517
.0271
.0026
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
.996
.996
.996
10
10
10
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0656
.0345
.0033
.2781
.2781
.2781
4.327
4.327
4.327
4.122
2.164
0.205
.0656
.0345
.0033
.1129
.0592
.0056
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
.996
.996
.996
10
10
10
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0504
.0265
.0025
.2913
.2913
.2914
4.127
4.127
4.127
3.931
2.063
0.196
.0504
.0265
.0025
.0976
.0512
.0049
.2405
.0850
.0070
4.827
7.169
8.202
.0836
.1237
.1410
.1460
.2139
.2415
Table 1:
The table shows the values of the reported normalized daily VaR (v), the RRA coefficient of
the dual value function (Γ), the upper bound on the portfolio allocation to the risky asset (π̄), the portfolio
allocation to the risky asset (π), the true normalized 90% VaR (v.90 ) and the true normalized 99% VaR
(v.99 ) in the presence of capital requirements, as well as the RRA coefficient (ΓU ), the portfolio allocation
U
U
to the risky asset (π U ) and the true normalized 90% and 99% VaRs (v.90
and v.99
) in the unconstrained
case.
20
Parameter values: γ = .50, ε = 0, β = .08, λ = .01, τ = .004, m = 1
t
i
k
LR
v
Γ
π̄
π
v.90
v.99
ΓU
πU
U
v.90
U
v.99
0
0
0
0
0
0
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5025
.5024
.5024
2.830
2.830
2.830
2.311
1.213
0.115
.0403
.0213
.0020
.0706
.0370
.0035
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
0
0
0
0
0
0
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5113
.5113
.5113
2.601
2.601
2.601
2.271
1.192
0.113
.0396
.0209
.0020
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
0
0
0
5
5
5
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5027
.5026
.5026
2.826
2.826
2.826
2.310
1.213
0.115
.0404
.0213
.0020
.0707
.0370
.0035
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
0
0
0
5
5
5
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0597
.0313
.0030
.5125
.5124
.5124
2.595
2.595
2.595
2.266
1.189
0.113
.0396
.0209
.0020
.0597
.0313
.0030
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
0
0
0
10
10
10
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5025
.5024
.5024
2.830
2.830
2.830
2.311
1.213
0.115
.0404
.0213
.0020
.0706
.0370
.0035
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
0
0
0
10
10
10
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5113
.5112
.5112
2.601
2.601
2.601
2.271
1.192
0.113
.0396
.0209
.0020
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5000
.2078
.0149
2.323
2.933
3.892
.0405
.0513
.0679
.0723
.0923
.1212
.996
.996
.996
0
0
0
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5025
.5024
.5024
2.830
2.830
2.830
2.311
1.213
0.115
.0405
.0213
.0020
.0706
.0372
.0035
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
.996
.996
.996
0
0
0
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5113
.5113
.5113
2.601
2.601
2.601
2.271
1.192
0.113
.0393
.0207
.0020
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
.996
.996
.996
5
5
5
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5027
.5026
.5026
2.826
2.826
2.826
2.310
1.213
0.115
.0407
.0213
.0020
.0708
.0372
.0035
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
.996
.996
.996
5
5
5
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0597
.0313
.0030
.5123
.5123
.5123
2.595
2.595
2.595
2.267
1.190
0.113
.0394
.0208
.0020
.0597
.0313
.0030
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
.996
.996
.996
10
10
10
9.49
9.49
9.49
.05
.50
.95
.0777
.0408
.0039
.5025
.5024
.5024
2.830
2.830
2.830
2.311
1.213
0.115
.0407
.0215
.0020
.0709
.0374
.0035
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
.996
.996
.996
10
10
10
12.65
12.65
12.65
.05
.50
.95
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5113
.5113
.5113
2.601
2.601
2.601
2.271
1.192
0.113
.0398
.0209
.0020
.0596
.0313
.0030
.5000
.1922
.0119
2.322
3.172
4.845
.0405
.0557
.0846
.0723
.1010
.1509
Table 2:
The