Monday,
July 8, 2002
Part III
Library of Congress
Copyright Office
37 CFR Part 261
Determination of Reasonable Rates and
Terms for the Digital Performance of
Sound Recordings and Ephemeral
Recordings; Final Rule
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
PO 00000
Frm 00001
Fmt 4717
Sfmt 4717
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
45240
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
LIBRARY OF CONGRESS
Copyright Office
37 CFR Part 261
[Docket No. 2000–9 CARP DTRA 1&2]
Determination of Reasonable Rates
and Terms for the Digital Performance
of Sound Recordings and Ephemeral
Recordings
AGENCY: Copyright Office, Library of
Congress.
ACTION: Final rule and order.
SUMMARY: The Librarian of Congress,
upon recommendation of the Register of
Copyrights, is announcing the
determination of the reasonable rates
and terms for two compulsory licenses,
permitting certain digital performances
of sound recordings and the making of
ephemeral recordings.
EFFECTIVE DATE: July 8, 2002.
ADDRESSES: The full text of the public
version of the Copyright Arbitration
Royalty Panel’s report to the Librarian of
Congress is available for inspection and
copying during normal working hours
in the Office of the General Counsel,
James Madison Memorial Building,
Room LM–403, First and Independence
Avenue, SE., Washington, DC 20540.
The report is also posted on the
Copyright Office website at http://
www.copyright.gov/carp/
webcasting_rates.html.
FOR FURTHER INFORMATION CONTACT:
David O. Carson, General Counsel, or
Tanya Sandros, Senior Attorney,
Copyright Arbitration Royalty Panel
(CARP), P.O. Box 70977, Southwest
Station, Washington, DC 20024.
Telephone (202) 707–8380. Telefax:
(202) 707–8366.
SUPPLEMENTARY INFORMATION:
Table of Contents
I. Background
II. The CARP Proceeding to Set Reasonable
Rates and Terms
A. The Parties
B. The position of the parties at the
commencement of the proceeding
1. Rates proposed by Copyright Owners
2. Rates proposed by Services
C. The Panel’s determination of reasonable
rates and a minimum fee
III. The Librarian’s Scope of Review of the
Panel’s Report
IV. The CARP Report: Review and
Recommendation of the Register of
Copyrights
A. Establishing Appropriate Rates
1. The ‘‘Willing Buyer/Willing Seller
Standard’’
2. Hypothetical Marketplace/Actual
Marketplace
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
3. Benchmarks for setting market rates:
voluntary agreements vs. musical works
fees
a. Fees paid for use of musical works
b. Voluntary agreements
4. Alternative methodology: Percentage-ofrevenue
5. The Yahoo! rates—evidence of a unitary
marketplace value
6. Are rates based on the Yahoo! agreement
indicative of marketplace rates?
7. Should a different rate be established for
commercial broadcasters streaming their
own AM/FM programming?
8. Methodology for calculating the
statutory rates for the webcasting license
a. Calculation of the unitary rate
b. The 150-mile exemption
9. Rates for other webcasting services and
programming
a. Business to business webcasting services
b. Listener-influenced services
c. Other types of transmissions
10. Rates for transmissions made by nonCPB, noncommercial stations
11. Consideration of request for diminished
rates and long song surcharge
12. Methodology for estimating the number
of performances
13. Discount for Promotion and Security
14. Ephemeral recordings for services
operating under the section 114 license
15. Minimum fees
16. Ephemeral recordings for business
establishment services (‘‘BES’’)
a. Rates for use of the statutory license
b. Minimum fee
17. Effective period for proposed rates
B. Terms
1. Disputed terms
a. Definitions
b. Designated Agent for Unaffiliated
Copyright Owners
c. Gross proceeds
2. Terms Not Disputed by the Parties
a. Limitation of Liability
b. Deductions from Royalties for
Designated Agent’s Costs
c. Ephemeral Recording
d. Definition of ‘‘Listener’’
e. Timing of Payment by Receiving Agent
to Designated Agent
f. Allocation of Royalties among
Designated Agents and Among Copyright
Owners and Performers
g. Choice of Designated Agent by
Performers
h. Performer’s Right to Audit
i. Effective date
V. Conclusion
VI. The Order of the Librarian of Congress
I. Background
In 1995, Congress enacted the Digital
Performance Right in Sound Recordings
Act (‘‘DPRA’’), Public Law 104–39,
which created an exclusive right for
copyright owners of sound recordings,
subject to certain limitations, to perform
publicly their sound recordings by
means of certain digital audio
transmissions. Among the limitations on
the performance right was the creation
of a new compulsory license for
nonexempt, noninteractive, digital
PO 00000
Frm 00002
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
subscription transmissions. 17 U.S.C.
114(f).
The scope of this license was
expanded in 1998 upon passage of the
Digital Millennium Copyright Act of
1998 (‘‘DMCA’’ or ‘‘Act’’), Public Law
105–304, in order to allow a nonexempt
eligible nonsubscription transmission 1
(the ‘‘webcasting license’’) and a
nonexempt transmission by a
preexisting satellite digital audio radio
service to perform publicly a sound
recording in accordance with the terms
and rates of the statutory license. 17
U.S.C. 114(a). In addition to expanding
the section 114 license, the DMCA also
created a new statutory license for the
making of an ‘‘ephemeral recording’’ of
a sound recording by certain
transmitting organizations (the
‘‘ephemeral recording license’’). 17
U.S.C. 112(e). The new statutory license
allows entities that transmit
performances of sound recordings to
business establishments, pursuant to the
limitations set forth in section
114(d)(1)(C)(iv), to make an ephemeral
recording of a sound recording for
purposes of a later transmission. The
new license also provides a means by
which a transmitting entity with a
statutory license under section 114(f)
can make more than the one
phonorecord permitted under the
exemption set forth in section 112(a). 7
U.S.C. 112(e).
The statutory scheme for establishing
reasonable terms and rates is the same
for both of the new licenses. The terms
and rates for the two new statutory
licenses may be determined by
voluntary agreement among the affected
parties, or if necessary, through
compulsory arbitration conducted
pursuant to Chapter 8 of the Copyright
Act.
In this case, interested parties were
unable to negotiate an industry-wide
agreement. Therefore, a Copyright
Arbitration Royalty Panel (‘‘CARP’’) was
convened to consider proposals from
interested parties and, based upon the
written record created during this
process, to recommend rates and terms
for both the webcasting license and the
ephemeral recording license.
1 An ‘‘eligible nonsubscription transmission’’ is a
noninteractive, digital audio transmission which, as
the name implies, does not require a subscription
for receiving the transmission. The transmission
must also be made a part of a service that provides
audio programming consisting in a whole or in part
of performances of sound recordings; the purpose
of which is to provide audio or entertainment
programming, but not to sell, advertise, or promote
particular goods or services.
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
II. The CARP Proceeding to Set
Reasonable Rates and Terms
These proceedings began on
November 27, 1998, when the Copyright
Office announced a six-month voluntary
negotiation period to set rates and terms
for the webcasting license and the
ephemeral recording license for the first
license period covering October 28,
1998–December 31, 2000. 63 FR 6555
(November 27, 1998). During this
period, the parties negotiated a number
of private agreements in the
marketplace, but no industry-wide
agreement was reached. Consequently,
in accordance with the procedural
requirements, the Recording Industry
Association of America, Inc. (‘‘RIAA’’)
petitioned the Copyright Office on July
23, 1999, to commence a CARP
proceeding to set the rates and terms for
these licenses. The Office responded by
setting a schedule for the CARP
proceeding. See 64 FR 52107 (Sept. 27,
1999).
However, the schedule proved
unworkable for the parties. RIAA filed
a motion with the Copyright Office on
November 23, 1999, requesting a
postponement of the date for filing
direct cases. It argued that the Office
should provide more time for the parties
to prepare their cases in light of the
complexity of the issues and the record
number of new participants. The Office
granted this request and held a meeting
to clarify the procedural aspects of the
proceeding, especially for the new
participants, and to discuss a new
schedule for the arbitration phase of the
process. Order in Docket No. 99–6
CARP DTRA (dated December 22, 1999).
In the meantime, the Office commenced
the six-month negotiation period for the
second license period, covering January
1, 2001–December 31, 2002. 66 FR 2194
(January 13, 2000). Ultimately, the
Copyright Office consolidated these two
proceedings into a single proceeding in
which one CARP would set rates and
terms for the two license periods for
both the webcasting license and the
ephemeral recording license. See Order
in Docket Nos. 99–6 CARP DTRA and
2000–3 CARP DTRA 2 (December 4,
2000). The 180-day period for the
consolidated proceeding began on July
30, 2001, and on February 20, 2002, the
panel submitted its report (the ‘‘CARP
Report’’ or ‘‘Report’’), in which it
proposed rates and terms to the
Copyright Office. It is the decision of
this Panel that is the basis for the
Librarian’s decision today.2
2 Section 802 (e) of the Copyright Act requires the
CARP to report its determination concerning the
royalty fee to the Librarian of Congress 180 days
after the initiation of a proceeding. In this particular
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
A. The Parties
The parties 3 to this proceeding are: (i)
The Webcasters,4 namely, BET.com,
Comedy Central, Echo Networks, Inc.,
Listen.com, Live365.com, MTVi Group,
LLC, Myplay, Inc., NetRadio
Corporation, Radio Active Media
Partners, Inc.; RadioWave.com, Inc.,
Spinner Networks Inc. and XACT Radio
Network LLC; (ii) the FCC-licensed
radio Broadcasters,5 namely,
Susquehanna Radio Corporation, Clear
Channel Communications Inc.,
Entercom Communications Corporation,
Infinity Broadcasting Corporation, and
National Religious Broadcasters Music
License Committee (collectively ‘‘the
Broadcasters’’); (iii) the Business
Establishment Services,6 namely, DMX/
AEI Music Inc. (also referred to as
‘‘Background Music Services’’); (iv)
American Federation of Television and
Radio Artists (‘‘AFTRA’’); 7 (v)
American Federation of Musicians of
the United States and Canada
instance, the Panel submitted its report
approximately three weeks later than anticipated
under this provision due to a suspension of the
proceedings during the period November 9, 2001,
through December 2, 2001. The Copyright Office
granted the suspension at the parties’ request in
order to allow them to engage in further settlement
discussions. At the same time, the Office granted
the Panel an additional period of time,
commensurate with the suspension period, for
hearing evidence and preparing its report. See
Order, Docket No. 2000–9 CARP DTRA 1&2
(November 9, 2001). Additional details concerning
the earlier procedural aspects of this proceeding are
set forth in the CARP Report at pp. 10–18.
3 At the outset of the proceeding, Webcaster
parties also included Coollink Broadcast Network,
Everstream, Inc., Incanta, Inc., Launch Media, Inc.,
MusicMatch, Inc., Univision Online, and Westwind
Media.com, Inc., which have since withdrawn or
been dismissed from the proceeding. Late in the
proceeding, National Public Radio (‘‘NPR’’) reached
a private settlement with RIAA and withdrew prior
to the conclusion of the 180-day hearing period.
Because RIAA, AFTRA, AFM, and AFIM propose
the same rates and take similar positions on most
issues, they are sometimes referred to collectively
as ‘‘RIAA’’ or ‘‘Copyright Owners and Performers’’
for convenience. Similarly, Webcasters,
Broadcasters, and the Business Establishment
Services are sometimes referred to collectively as
‘‘the Services.’’
4 The Webcasters are Internet services that each
employ a technology known as ‘‘streaming,’’ but
comprise a range of different business models and
music programming.
5 The Broadcasters are commercial AM or FM
radio stations that are licensed by the Federal
Communications Commission (‘‘FCC’’).
6 The Business Establishment Services, DMX/AEI
Music, deliver sound recordings to business
establishments for the enjoyment of the
establishments’ customers. See Knittel W.D.T. 4.
DMX/AEI Music is the successor company resulting
from a merger between AEI Music Network, Inc.
(‘‘AEI’’) and DMX Music, Inc. (‘‘DMX’’).
7 AFTRA, the American Federation of Television
and Radio Artists, is a national labor organization
representing performers and newspersons. See Tr.
2830 (Himelfarb).
PO 00000
Frm 00003
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
45241
(‘‘AFM’’) ;8 (vi) Association For
Independent Music (‘‘AFIM’’) ;9 and
(vii) Recording Industry Association of
America, Inc. (‘‘RIAA’’).10 Music
Choice, a Business Establishment
Service, was initially a party to this
proceeding, but on March 26, 2001, it
filed a motion to withdraw from the
proceeding. Its motion was unopposed
and, on May 9, 2001, its motion to
withdraw was granted.
B. The Position of the Parties at the
Commencement of the Proceeding
1. Rates Proposed by Copyright Owners
RIAA proposed rates derived from an
analysis of 26 voluntarily negotiated
agreements between itself and
individual webcasters. RIAA claims that
these agreements ‘‘involve the same
buyer, the same seller, the same right,
the same copyrighted works, the same
time period and the same medium as
those in the marketplace that the CARP
must replicate.’’ CARP Report at 26,
citing RIAA PFFCL 11 (Introduction at
8). Based upon these agreements, RIAA
proposed the following rates for DMCA
compliant webcasting services:
(i) For basic ‘‘business to consumer’’
(B2C) webcasting services:
0.4c for each transmission of a sound
recording to a single listener, or 15% of
the service’s gross revenues.
(ii) For ‘‘business to business’’ (B2B)
webcasting services, where
transmissions are made as part of a
service that is syndicated to third-party
websites:
0.5c for each transmission of a sound
recording to a single listener
(iii) For ‘‘listener-influenced’’
webcasting services:
0.6c for each transmission of a sound
recording to a single listener
(iv) Minimum fee (subject to certain
qualifications): $5,000 per webcasting
service
8 AFM, the American Federation of Musicians, is
a labor organization representing professional
musicians. See Bradley W.D.T. 1.
9 AFIM, the Association For Independent Music,
is a trade association representing independent
record companies, wholesalers, distributors and
retailers. See Tr. 2830 (Himelfarb)
10 RIAA is a trade association representing record
companies, including the five ‘‘majors’’ and
numerous ‘‘independent’’ labels.
11 Hereinafter, references to proposed findings of
fact and conclusions of law shall be cited as
‘‘OFFCK’’ preceded by the name of the party that
submitted the filing followed by the paragraph
number. References to written direct testimony
shall be cited as ‘‘W.D.T.’’ preceded by the last
name of the witness and followed by a page
number. References 9to written rebuttal testimony
shall be cited as ‘‘W.R.T.’’ preceded by the last
name of the witness and followed by a page
number. References to the transcript shall be cited
asd ‘‘TR.’’ followed by the page number and the last
name of the witness.
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
45242
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
(v) Ephemeral license fee:
10% of each service’s performance
royalty fee payable under (i), (ii), or (iii).
For the section 112 license applicable
to the business establishment services,
the copyright owners proposed a rate set
at 10% of gross revenues with a
minimum fee of $50,000 a year.
2. Rates Proposed by Services
Webcasters proposed per-performance
and per-hour sound recording
performance fees, based upon an
economic model, that considered the
aggregate fees paid to the three
performance rights organizations
(ASCAP, BMI, and SESAC) that license
the public performances of musical
works for radio programs that are
broadcast over-the-air by FCC-licensed
broadcasters, by 872 radio stations
during 2000. From this model, the
webcasters derived a per-song and a perlistener hour base rate of 0.02¢ per song
and 0.3¢ per hour, respectively. These
figures were then adjusted to account
for a number of factors, including the
promotional value gained by the record
companies from the performance of
their works. This adjustment resulted in
a fee proposal of 0.014¢ per
performance or 0.21¢ per hour.
At the end of the proceeding,
Webcasters suggested in their proposed
findings of fact and conclusions of law
an alternative method for calculating
royalty fees, namely, a percentage-ofrevenue fee structure. Specifically,
Webcasters proposed a fee of 3% of a
webcaster’s gross revenues for all
services. The alternative proposal was
made with the understanding that the
service would be able to elect either
option.
Webcasters proposed no additional
fee for the making of ephemeral
recordings and a minimum fee of $250
per annum for each service operating
under the section 114 license.
The Business Establishment Services
who need only an ephemeral recording
license proposed a flat rate of $10,000
per year for each company.
C. The Panel’s Determination of
Reasonable Rates and a Minimum Fees
In this proceeding, the Panel had to
establish rates and terms of payment for
digital transmissions of sound
recordings made by noninteractive,
nonsubscription services and rates for
the making of ephemeral phonorecords
made pursuant to the section 112(e)
license; either to facilitate those
transmissions made or by business
establishments which are otherwise
exempt from the digital performance
right.
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
The proposed rates are set forth in
Appendix A of the CARP Report, which
is posted on the Copyright Office
website at: http://www.copyright.gov/
carp/webcasting_rates_a.pdf.
The proposed terms of payment may
be found in Appendix B of the CARP
Report, which is posted on the
Copyright Office website at: http://
www.copyright.gov/carp/
webcasting_rates_b.pdf.
III. The Librarian’s Scope of Review of
the Panel’s Report
The Copyright Royalty Tribunal
Reform Act of 1993 (the Reform Act),
Pub. L. No. 103–198, 107 Stat. 2304,
created a unique system of review of a
CARP’s determination. Typically, an
arbitrator’s decision is not reviewable,
but the Reform Act created two layers of
review that result in final orders: one by
the Librarian of Congress (Librarian) and
a second by the United States Court of
Appeals for the District of Columbia
Circuit. Section 802(f) of title 17 directs
the Librarian on the recommendation of
the Register of Copyrights either to
accept the decision of the CARP, or to
reject it. If the Librarian rejects it, he
must substitute his own determination
‘‘after full examination of the record
created in the arbitration proceeding.’’
17 U.S.C. 802(f). If the Librarian accepts
it, then the determination of the CARP
becomes the determination of the
Librarian. In either case, through
issuance of the Librarian’s Order, it is
his decision that will be subject to
review by the Court of Appeals. 17
U.S.C. 802(g).
The review process has been
thoroughly discussed in prior
recommendations of the Register of
Copyrights (Register) concerning rate
adjustments and royalty distribution
proceedings. See, e.g., Distribution of
1990, 1991, and 1992 Cable Royalties,
61 FR 55653 (1996); Rate Adjustment for
the Satellite Carrier Compulsory
License, 62 FR 55742 (October 28,
1997). Nevertheless, the discussion
merits repetition because of its
importance in reviewing each CARP
decision.
Section 802(f) of the Copyright Act
directs that the Librarian shall adopt the
report of the CARP, ‘‘unless the
Librarian finds that the determination is
arbitrary or contrary to the applicable
provisions of this title.’’ Neither the
Reform Act nor its legislative history
indicates what is meant specifically by
‘‘arbitrary,’’ but there is no reason to
conclude that the use of the term is any
different from the ‘‘arbitrary’’ standard
described in the Administrative
Procedure Act (APA), 5 U.S.C.
706(2)(A).
PO 00000
Frm 00004
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
Review of the case law applying the
APA ‘‘arbitrary’’ standard reveals six
factors or circumstances under which a
court is likely to find that an agency
acted arbitrarily. An agency action is
generally considered to be arbitrary
when:
1. It relies on factors that Congress did
not intend it to consider;
2. It fails to consider entirely an
important aspect of the problem that it
was solving;
3. It offers an explanation for its
decision that runs counter to the
evidence presented before it;
4. It issues a decision that is so
implausible that it cannot be explained
as a product of agency expertise or a
difference of viewpoint;
5. It fails to examine the data and
articulate a satisfactory explanation for
its action including a rational
connection between the facts found and
the choice made; and
6. Its action entails the unexplained
discrimination or disparate treatment of
similarly situated parties.
Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n. State Farm
Mutual Auto. Insurance Co., 463 U.S. 29
(1983); Celcom Communications Corp.
v. FCC, 789 F.2d 67 (D.C. Cir. 1986);
Airmark Corp. v. FAA, 758 F.2d 685
(D.C. Cir. 1985).
In reviewing the CARP’s decision, the
Librarian has been guided by these
principles and the prior decisions of the
District of Columbia Circuit in which
the court applied the ‘‘arbitrary and
capricious’’ standard of 5 U.S.C.
706(2)(A) to the determinations of the
former Copyright Royalty Tribunal
(hereinafter ‘‘CRT or Tribunal’’). See,
e.g, National Cable Tele. Ass’n v. CRT,
724 F.2d 176 (D.C. Cir. 1983) (applying
the Administrative Procedure Act’s
standard authorizing courts to set aside
agency action found to be arbitrary,
capricious, and abuse of discretion, or
otherwise in accordance with law.’’); see
also, Recording Industry Ass’n of
America v. CRT, 662 F.2d 1, 7–9 (D.C.
Cir. 1981); Amusement and Music
Operators Ass’n v. CRT, 676 F.2d 1144,
1149–52 (7th Cir.), cert denied, 459 U.S.
907 (1982); National Ass’n of
Broadcasters v. CRT, 675 F.2d 367, 375
n. 8 (D.C. Cir. 1982).
Review of judicial decisions regarding
Tribunal actions reveals a consistent
theme; while the Tribunal was granted
a relatively wide ‘‘zone of
reasonableness,’’ it was required to
articulate clearly the rationale for its
award of royalties to each claimant. See
National Ass’n of Broadcasters v. CRT,
772 F.2d 922 (D.C. Cir. 1985), cert.
denied, 475 U.S. 1035 (1986) (NAB v.
CRT); Christian Broadcasting Network v.
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
CRT, 720 F.2d 1295 (D.C. Cir. 1983)
(Christian Broadcasting v. CRT);
National Cable Television Ass’n v. CRT,
689 F.2d 1077 (D.C. Cir. 1982) (NCTA v.
CRT); Recording Indus. Ass’n of
America v. CRT, 662 F.2d 1 (D.C. Cir.
1981) (RIAA v. CRT). As the D.C. Circuit
succinctly noted:
We wish to emphasize * * * that precisely
because of the technical and discretionary
nature of the Tribunal’s work, we must
especially insist that it weigh all the relevant
considerations and that it set out its
conclusions in a form that permits us to
determine whether it has exercised its
responsibilities lawfully. * * *
Christian Broadcasting v. CRT, 720
F.2d at 1319 (D.C. Cir. 1983), quoting
NCTA v. CRT, 689 F.2d at 1091 (D.C.
Cir. 1982).
Because the Librarian is reviewing the
CARP decision under the same
‘‘arbitrary’’ standard used by the courts
to review the Tribunal, he must be
presented by the CARP with a rational
analysis of its decision, setting forth
specific findings of fact and conclusions
of law. This requirement of every CARP
report is confirmed by the legislative
history of the Reform Act which notes
that a ‘‘clear report setting forth the
panel’s reasoning and findings will
greatly assist the Librarian of Congress.’’
H.R. Rep. No. 103–286, at 13 (1993).
This goal cannot be reached by
‘‘attempt[ing] to distinguish apparently
inconsistent awards with simple,
undifferentiated allusions to a 10,000
page record.’’ Christian Broadcasting v.
CRT, 720 F.2d at 1319.
It is the task of the Register to review
the report and make her
recommendation to the Librarian as to
whether it is arbitrary or contrary to the
provisions of the Copyright Act and, if
so, whether, and in what manner, the
Librarian should substitute his own
determination. 17 U.S.C. 802(f).
IV. The CARP Report: Review and
Recommendation of the Register of
Copyrights
The law gives the Register the
responsibility to review the CARP report
and make recommendations to the
Librarian whether to adopt or reject the
Panel’s determination. In doing so, she
reviews the Panel’s report, the parties’
post-panel submissions, and the record
evidence.
After carefully considering the Panel’s
report and the record in this proceeding,
the Register has concluded that the rates
proposed by the Panel for use of the
webcasting license do not reflect the
rates that a willing buyer and willing
seller would agree upon in the
marketplace. Therefore, the Register has
made a recommendation that the
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
Librarian reject the proposed rates
($0.14 per performance for Internet-only
transmissions and $0.07 per
performance for radio retransmissions)
for the section 114 license and
substitute his own determination (0.07c
per performance for both types of
transmissions), based upon the Panel’s
analysis of the hypothetical
marketplace, and its reliance upon
contractual agreements negotiated in the
marketplace.
These changes necessitate an
adjustment to the proposed rates for
non-CPB, noncommercial
broadcasters 12 for Internet-only
transmissions as well. The adjusted rate
for archived programming subsequently
transmitted over the Internet,
substituted programming and up to two
side channels is 0.02¢, reflecting a
downward adjustment from the 0.05¢
rate proposed by the Panel. The new
rate for all other transmissions made by
non-CPB, noncommercial broadcasters
is 0.07¢ per performance per listener.
Using this methodology, the Register
recommends that the Librarian also
reject the Panel’s determination of a rate
for the making of ephemeral recordings
by those Licensees operating under the
webcasting license. Because the Panel
had made an earlier determination not
to consider 25 of the 26 contracts
submitted by RIAA for the purpose of
setting a rate for the webcasting license,
it was arbitrary for the Panel to use
these same rejected licenses to set the
Ephemeral License Fee. See section
IV.13 herein for discussion.
Consequently, the Register proposes a
downward adjustment—from 9% of the
performance royalties paid to 8.8%—to
the Ephemeral License Fee to remove
the effect of the discarded licenses.
In determining the Ephemeral License
Fee for Business Establishment Services
operating under an exemption to the
digital performance right, the CARP
considered separate licenses negotiated
in the marketplace between individual
record companies and these services. Its
reliance on these agreements as an
adequate benchmark for purposes of
setting the rate for the section 112
license was well-founded and supported
by the record. Therefore, the Register
recommends adopting the Panel’s
proposal of setting the Ephemeral
License Fee for Business Establishment
Services at 10% of the service’s gross
proceeds. However, the Register cannot
support the Panel’s recommendation to
set the minimum fee applicable to these
12 A non-CPB, noncommercial broadcaster is a
Public Broadcasting Entity as defined in 17 U.S.C.
118(g) that is not qualified to receive funding from
the Corporation for Public Broadcasting pursuant to
the criteria set forth in 47 U.S.C. 396.
PO 00000
Frm 00005
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
45243
services for its use of the ephemeral
license at $500 when clear evidence
exists in the contractual agreements to
establish a much higher range of values
for setting the minimum fee.
Consequently, the Register evaluated the
contracts and proposed a minimum fee
consistent with the record evidence.
The result is a minimum fee of $10,000
per license pro rated on a monthly basis.
Section 802(f) states that ‘‘[i]f the
Librarian rejects the determination of
the arbitration panel, the Librarian shall,
before the end of that 90-day period,
and after full examination of the record
created in the arbitration proceeding,
issue an order setting the royalty fee or
distribution of fees, as the case may be.’’
During that 90-day period, the Register
reviewed the Panel’s report and made a
recommendation to the Librarian to
accept in part and reject in part the
Panel’s report, for the reasons cited
herein. The Librarian accepted this
recommendation and, on May 21, 2002,
he issued an order rejecting the Panel’s
determination proposing rates and terms
for the webcasting license and the
ephemeral recording license. See Order,
Docket No. 2000–9 CARP DTRA 1&2
(dated May 21, 2002).
The full review of the Register and her
corresponding recommendations are
presented herein. Within the limited
scope of the Librarian’s review of this
proceeding, ‘‘the Librarian will not
second guess a CARP’s balance and
consideration of the evidence, unless its
decision runs completely counter to the
evidence presented to it.’’ Rate
Adjustment for the Satellite Carrier
Compulsory License, 62 FR 55757
(1997), citing 61 FR 55663 (October 28,
1996) (Distribution of 1990, 1991 and
1992 Cable Royalties). Accordingly, the
Register accepts the Panel’s weighing of
the evidence and will not question
findings and conclusions which proceed
directly from the arbitrators’
consideration of factual evidence. The
Register, however, may reject a finding
of the Panel where it is clear that its
determination is not supported by the
evidence in the record.
A. Establishing Appropriate Rates
1. The ‘‘Willing Buyer/Willing Seller
Standard’’
Sections 112(e)(4) and 114(f)(2)(B), of
title 17 of the U.S.C., provide that ‘‘the
copyright arbitration royalty panel shall
establish rates and terms that most
clearly represent the rates and terms
that would have been negotiated in the
marketplace between a willing buyer
and a willing seller,’’ and enumerate
two factors that the panel shall consider
in making its decisions: (1) The effect of
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
45244
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
the use of the sound recordings on the
sale of phonorecords, and (2) the
relative contributions made by both
industries in bringing these works to the
public. In applying this standard, the
Panel determined that it was to consider
the enumerated factors along with all
other relevant factors identified by the
parties, but that it was not to accord the
listed factors special consideration.
Report at 21; see also Final Rule and
Order, Rate Adjustment for the Satellite
Carrier Compulsory License, Docket No.
96–3 CARP SRA, 62 FR 55742, 55746
(October 28, 1997).
Nevertheless, when the Panel
considered the record evidence offered
to establish a marketplace rate, it paid
close attention to the two factors set
forth in the statute. In analyzing the first
factor, which focuses on the interplay
between webcasting and sales of
phonorecords, the panel found that the
evidence offered during the proceeding
was insufficient to demonstrate whether
webcasting promoted or displaced sales
of sound recordings. RIAA’s evidence to
demonstrate that performances of their
sound recordings over the Internet
displace record sales consisted of
unsupported opinion testimony and
consequently, the Panel afforded it no
weight. Report at 33. Similarly, the
Panel rejected the Webcasters’
contention that webcasting promoted
sales, affording little weight to its
empirical studies. It concluded that the
Sounddata survey 13 was not useful for
purposes of this proceeding because it
focused on the promotional value of
traditional radio broadcasts and not the
promotional value of webcasting. Id.
Likewise, the Panel rejected a study by
Professor Michael Mazis 14 because the
13 Michael Fine is an expert witness for the
Webcasters and Broadcasters. He was the chief
executive officer to Soundata, SoundScan and
Broadcast Data Systems until December 31, 2000,
and is now a management consultant to the firms
operating these services. He analyzed data collected
by these services to determine the promotional
effect upon record sales from radio retransmissions
and Internet-only transmissions and the
displacement effect of record sales due to copying
of sound recordings from Internet transmissions.
Fine’s W.D.T. at 1.
14 Professor Mazis is a Professor in the Kogod
School of Business, American University, who
testified on behalf of the Webcasters and
Broadcasters. He designed a survey study to analyze
usage patterns of people who listen to simulcast of
a radio station’s over-the-air broadcast programming
and transmissions made by services transmitting
solely over the Internet. Specifically, the study was
designed to measure:
a. The effect listening to transmissions over the
Internet had on a listener’s music purchases;
b. the extent to which listeners to radio
retransmissions are either listeners from the
broadcaster’s local market or non-local listeners;
c. the amount of time spent listening to
programming on the Internet and the proportion of
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
response rates in the survey study fell
below generally acceptable standards.
All in all, the evidence on either side
was not persuasive. Consequently, the
Panel concluded that, for the time
period under consideration, ‘‘the net
impact of Internet webcasting on record
sales [was] indeterminate.’’ Id. at 34.
Broadcasters, however, disagree with
the Panel’s conclusions. They argue that
the Panel should have made an
adjustment for the promotional value of
the transmissions, noting that the statute
singled out this factor for consideration
when setting the rates. Broadcasters
Petition at 38. They further contend that
the record demonstrates that ‘‘the
promotional value of radio play should
be far and away the most significant
factor in determining the fair market
value of broadcasters simulcast rates.’’
Id. at 39–40. But all the evidence cited
in the record references the
interrelationship between radio stations
and record companies in the analog
world. As noted above, the Panel
considered the evidence but did not
find it persuasive.
Where the Panel makes a decision
based upon its weighing of the
evidence, the Register will not disturb
its findings and conclusions that
proceed directly from the Panel’s
consideration of the factual evidence.
Thus, the Register accepts the Panel’s
conclusion that performances of sound
recordings over the Internet did not
significantly stimulate record sales.
More importantly, though, the Panel
correctly found that promotional value
is a factor to be considered in
determining rates under the willing
buyer/willing seller model, and does not
constitute an additional standard or
policy consideration to be used after
rates are set to adjust a base rate
upwards or downwards. Report at 21.
Therefore, the effect of any promotional
value attributable to a radio
retransmission would already be
reflected in the rates for these
transmissions reached through armslength negotiations in the marketplace.
As for the second factor, the Panel
found that both copyright owners and
licensees made significant creative,
technological and financial
contributions. It concluded, however,
that it was not necessary to gauge with
specificity the value of these
contributions in the case where actual
agreements voluntarily negotiated in the
marketplace existed, since such
that time spent listening to music programming
versus non-music programming; and
d. the reasons why people visit radio station
websites and the activities they engage in when
they visit these sites. Mazis’ W.D.T. at 1–2.
PO 00000
Frm 00006
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
considerations, including any
significant promotional value of the
transmissions, would already have been
factored into the agreed upon price. Id.
at 35–36. This is not a contested finding.
It is also important at the outset of
this review to distinguish the willing
buyer/willing seller standard to be used
in this proceeding from the standard
that applies when setting rates for
subscription services that operated
under the section 114 license. They are
not the same. Section 114(f)(1)(B),
governing subscription services,
requires a CARP to consider the
objectives set forth in section 801(b)(1),
as well as rates and terms for
comparable types of digital audio
transmission services established
through voluntary negotiations. See
Final Rule and Order, 63 FR 25394,
25399 (May 8, 1998). This standard for
setting rates for the subscription
services is policy-driven, whereas the
standard for setting rates for
nonsubscription services set forth in
section 114(f)(2)(B) is strictly fair market
value—willing buyer/willing seller.
Thus, any argument that the two rates
should be equal as a matter of law is
without merit. See, e.g., Webcasters
Petition at 4 (comparing rates set for
preexisting subscription services under
the policy driven standard with the
proposed marketplace rates for
nonsubscription services and inferring
that the rates should be similar).
2. Hypothetical Marketplace/Actual
Marketplace
To set rates based on a willing buyer/
willing seller standard, the CARP first
had to define the relevant marketplace
in which such rates would be set. It
determined, and the parties agreed, that
the rates should be those that a willing
buyer and willing seller would have
agreed upon in a hypothetical
marketplace that was not constrained by
a compulsory license. The CARP then
had to define the parameters of the
marketplace: the buyers, the sellers, and
the product.
In this configuration of the
marketplace, the willing buyers are the
services which may operate under the
webcasting license (DMCA-compliant
services), the willing sellers are record
companies, and the product consists of
a blanket license from each record
company which allows use of that
company’s complete repertoire of sound
recordings. Report at 24. Because of the
diversity among the buyers and the
sellers, the CARP noted that one would
expect ‘‘a range of negotiated rates,’’ and
so interpreted the statutory standard as
‘‘the rates to which, absent special
circumstances, most willing buyers and
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
willing sellers would agree’’ in a
competitive marketplace.15 Id. at 25.
The Services take issue with the
Panel’s analysis of the hypothetical
marketplace. They argue that the willing
sellers should be considered as a group
of hypothetical ‘‘competing collectives
each offering access to the range of
sound recordings required by the
Services,’’ and not, as the Panel
contends, viewed as individual record
companies. Broadcasters Petition at 9;
Webcasters Petition at 9–10. It is hard to
see, however, how competition would
be stimulated in a marketplace where
every seller offers the exact same
product and where more likely than not,
the sellers would act in concert to
extract monopolistic prices. Possibly
sellers would choose to undercut each
other, but at some point the price would
stabilize. In any event, the Services
failed to explain how such collectives
would operate in a competitive
marketplace. Consequently, the Register
rejects the Webcasters’ challenge to the
Panel’s definition on this point and
adopts the Panel’s characterization of
the relevant marketplace, recognizing
that for purposes of this proceeding, the
major record companies are represented
by a single entity, the RIAA.
Turning next to the actual
marketplace in which RIAA negotiated
agreements with individual services, the
Services voice a number of objections to
the Panel’s decision to rely on the 26
voluntary agreements offered into
evidence by RIAA. Specifically, the
Services object to the use of the
voluntary agreements because they fail
to exhibit a range of negotiated rates
among diverse buyers and sellers.
Broadcasters Petition at 10; Webcasters
Petition at 10. They also question the
validity of relying on agreements
negotiated during the early stages of a
newly emerging industry, noting the
Panel’s admonition to approach such
agreements with caution. Report at 47.
The reason for the warning was Dr.
Jaffe’s 16 stated concern that such
licenses ‘‘may not reflect fully educated
assessments of the nascent businesses’’
long-term prospects.’’
The Services also argue that the
existence of the antitrust exemption in
the statutory license gave RIAA an
15 The panel used the same analysis for setting the
rates for the ephemeral recording license because
the statutory language defining the standard for
setting rates for the ephemeral recording license is
nearly identical to the standard set forth in section
114.
16 Adam Jaffe is a Professor of Economics at
Brandeis University. He is also the Chair of the
Department of Economics and the Chair of the
University Intellectual Property Policy Committee.
He testified on behalf of the Webcasters and the
Broadcasters.
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
unfair bargaining advantage over the
Services because RIAA represented the
five major record companies who
together owned most of the works. They
contend that RIAA used its superior
market power to negotiate supracompetitive prices with Services who
could not match either RIAA’s power in
the marketplace or its sophistication in
negotiating contracts. Moreover, they
utterly reject the Panel’s determination
that RIAA’s perceived market power
was tempered by the existence of the
statutory license, which, for purposes of
negotiating a fair rate for use of sound
recordings, leveled the playing field.
Webcasters Petition at 12.
Not surprisingly, RIAA agrees with
the Panel on this issue. It maintains that
the statutory license offers the Services
two clear advantages which more than
offset any perceived advantage the RIAA
may have had in negotiating a voluntary
agreement. First, the license eliminates
the usual transaction costs associated
with negotiating separate licenses with
each of the copyright owners. Second,
services may avoid litigation costs
associated with setting the rates for a
statutory license provided they choose
not to participate in the CARP process.
RIAA reply at 12.
In essence, both sides articulate valid
positions which are supported by the
record. RIAA is clearly an established
market force with extensive resources
and sophistication. In fact, the Panel
found that when RIAA negotiated with
less sophisticated buyers who could not
wait for the outcome of this proceeding,
the rates were above-market value, and
therefore, not considered by this CARP.
Report at 54–56. Nevertheless, it would
make no sense for RIAA to take any
other position in a marketplace
negotiation. Sellers expect to make a
profit and will extract from the market
what they can, just as buyers will do
everything in their power to get the
product at the lowest possible price.
These are the fundamental principles
guiding marketplace negotiations.
Such negotiations, however, were
few. For the most part, webcasters chose
not to enter into negotiations for
voluntary agreements, knowing that
they could continue to operate and wait
for the CARP to establish a rate. Such
actions on the part of the users clearly
impeded serious negotiations in the
marketplace and support the CARP’s
observation that the statutory license
had a countervailing effect on the
negotiation process and limited the
ability of RIAA to exert undue
marketplace power. See Tr. 9075–77,
9490–94 (Marks) (explaining the
difficulties of bringing webcasters to the
negotiating table due to the statutory
PO 00000
Frm 00007
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
45245
license). Thus, the CARP could only
consider negotiated rates for the rights
covered by the statutory license that
were contained in an agreement
between RIAA and a Service with
comparable resources and market
power.
The only agreement that met these
criteria was the Yahoo!17 agreement.
The Panel found that both parties to that
agreement entered into negotiations in
good faith and on equal footing.
Moreover, RIAA’s negotiating advantage
disappeared. RIAA could not extract
super-competitive rates because Yahoo!
brought comparable resources,
sophistication, and market power to the
negotiating table.
Moreover, Yahoo! could have
continued to operate under the license
and wait for the outcome of this
proceeding. Yet, Yahoo!, unlike most of
the other Services, did not take this
course of action. It wanted a negotiated
agreement so that it could fully develop
its business model based on certainty as
to the costs of the use of the sound
recordings. Consequently, it had every
incentive to negotiate a rate that
reflected its perception of the value of
the digital performance right in light of
its needs and position in the
marketplace. Had RIAA insisted upon a
super competitive rate, Yahoo! could
have walked away and waited for the
CARP to set the rates. RIAA Reply at 13.
Thus, it was not arbitrary for the Panel
to consider the negotiated agreement
between Yahoo! and RIAA. It met all the
criteria identified by the CARP
(discussed above) that characterized the
hypothetical marketplace: Yahoo! was a
DMCA-compliant Service; RIAA
represented the interests of five
independent record companies, and the
license granted the same rights as those
offered under the webcasting and the
ephemeral recording licenses.
The Webcasters make one final
argument concerning use of licenses
negotiated in the marketplace. They
fault the Panel for its reliance on a
contract for which there was no prior
marketplace precedent for setting a rate.
Webcasters Petition at 15. Yet, that
alone cannot be a reason to reject
17 Yahoo! is a streaming service which provides
a retransmissions of AM/FM radio stations and
programming from other webcaster sites. Report at
61. Yahoo! is also a global Internet
communications, commerce and media company,
offering comprehensive services to more than 200
million users each month. Content for its features
like Yahoo! Finance, Yahoo! News, and Yahoo!
Sports, are typically licensed from third parties.
Mandelbrot W.D.T. ¶ 3–5.
The Panel was well aware of the many faces of
Yahoo! Nevertheless, it found no reason to reject
the Yahoo! agreement merely because it offered
other business services. See Report at 76, in 53.
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
45246
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
consideration of agreements negotiated
in the marketplace, albeit at an early
stage in the development of the
industry. At some point, rates must be
set. Such rates then become the baseline
for future market negotiations. RIAA
recognized an opportunity to participate
in this initial phase and moved forward
to negotiate contracts with users with
the intention of using these contracts to
indicate what a willing buyer would pay
in the marketplace. However, that was
easier said than done. As discussed
above, most Webcasters chose not to
enter into marketplace agreements,
preferring to wait for the outcome of the
CARP proceeding in the hope of getting
a low rate. Clearly, such resistance to
enter into good faith negotiations made
it difficult for the copyright owners to
gauge the market accurately and find
out just what a willing buyer would be
willing to pay for the right to transmit
a sound recording over the Internet.
3. Benchmarks for Setting Market Rates:
Voluntary Agreements vs. Musical
Works Fees
The parties offer two very different
methods for setting the webcasting rates.
RIAA argued that the best evidence of
the value of the digital performance
right is the actual rates individual
services agreed to pay for the right to
transmit sound recordings over the
Internet. In support of its position, it
offered into evidence 26 separate
agreements it had negotiated in the
marketplace prior to the initiation of the
CARP proceeding. The Services take a
different approach. They dispute the
validity of the contracts as a bases for
marketplace rates and offer in their
place a theoretical model (the ‘‘Jaffe
model’’) predicated on the fees
commercial broadcasters pay to use
musical works in their over-the-air AM/
FM broadcast programs.
The Jaffe model builds on the premise
that in the hypothetical marketplace,
copyright owners would license their
digital performance rights and
ephemeral recording rights at a rate no
higher than the rates music publishers
currently charge over-the-air radio
broadcasters for the right to publicly
perform their musical works.18 Report at
28, citing Webcasters PFFCL ¶¶ 276–78;
Jaffe W.D.T. 16–19. To find the rate
copyright owners would charge under
this model, Webcasters calculated a per
performance and a per hour rate by
using the aggregate fees that 872 over18 A ‘‘musical work’’ is a musical composition,
including any words accompanying the music. A
‘‘sound recording’’ is a work that results from the
fixation of a series of musical, spoken, or other
sounds, other than those accompanying a motion
picture or other audiovisual work.
VerDate May2002
18:26 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
the-air radio stations paid in 2000 to the
performing rights organizations BMI,
ASCAP, and SESAC.19 It combined the
fee data with data on listening
audiences obtained from Arbitron to
generate an average fee paid by an overthe-air broadcaster per ‘‘listening hour.’’
From this value, Webcasters calculated
a per performance fee by dividing the
‘‘listener hour’’ fee by the average
number of songs played per hour by
music-intensive format stations. Id.
These calculations yielded a per song
fee of 0.02¢ or, in the alternative, a per
listener hour fee of 0.22¢. For purposes
of webcasting, these values were
adjusted upward to reflect the fact that,
on average, webcasters play 15 songs
per hour, as compared to the 11 perhour played on over-the-air radio. The
webcaster per hour rate works out to be
0.3 instead of 0.2¢ per hour.
After carefully considering both
approaches, the Panel chose to focus on
the RIAA agreements. In rejecting Dr.
Jaffe’s theoretical model, the panel cited
three reasons for its conclusion. First,
the Panel expressed strong concern
regarding the construct of the model,
including: 1. The difficulty in
identifying all the factors that must be
considered in setting a price, and 2. The
inherent error associated with
predicating a prediction on a ‘‘string of
assumptions,’’ especially where the
level of confidence in many of the
assumptions is not high. Second, the
Panel was wary of analogizing the
market for the performance of musical
works with the market for the
performance of sound recordings,
finding instead that the two
marketplaces are distinct based upon
the difference in cost and demand
characteristics. And finally, the Panel
determined that the Jaffe model was
basically unreliable. It could not be used
to predict accurately the amount of
royalty fees owed to the performing
rights societies by a particular radio
station. It came to this conclusion after
using the model to predict the royalty
fees owed by a particular station and
comparing that figure to the amount the
radio station actually paid. For some
radio stations, the model severely
underestimated the amount owed to the
performing rights societies, thus,
drawing into serious question the
reliability of the model. Report at 42.
19 BMI, Inc., American Society for Composers,
Authors and Publishers, and SESAC, Inc. are
performing rights organizations that represent
songwriters, composers and music publisehrs in all
genres of music. These societies offer licenses and
collect and distribute royalty fees for the nondramatic public performances of the copyrighted
works of their members.
PO 00000
Frm 00008
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
a. Fees paid for use of musical works.
The Broadcasters and the Webcasters
fault the Panel for disregarding the fees
paid for musical works as a viable
benchmark. Webcasters Petition at 15,
47. They maintain that Dr. Jaffe’s
analysis proves that the value of the
performance of the sound recording is
no higher than the value of the
performance of the musical work.
Webcasters argue that the fees for
musical works constitute a valid
benchmark because these rates are the
result of transactions between willing
buyers and willing sellers over a long
period of time, in a marketplace that
shares economic characteristics with the
marketplace for sound recordings.
Webcasters Petition at 48. The
Broadcasters agree. They maintain that
even under the willing buyer/willing
seller standard, ‘‘the over-the-air
musical works license experience * * *
has resulted in fees ‘to which most
willing buyers and willing sellers [have]
agree[d]’ and constitute ‘comparable
agreements negotiated over a longer
period, which ha[ve] withstood ‘the test
of time.’ ’’ Broadcasters Petition at 45–
46, citing Report at 25, 47.
Broadcasters and Webcasters also
object to the Panel’s characterization of
its proposed benchmark as merely a
theoretical model. Webcasters Petition
at 51. They maintain that Dr. Jaffe’s
model was much more than a
theoretical model because it used actual
data from the musical works
marketplace to calculate an analogous
rate for use of sound recordings in the
digital marketplace. Consequently, these
Services contend that the Panel gave
inadequate consideration to their
proposed benchmark and rejected the
model out of hand because it was
purported to be only a theoretical model
based upon a number of untested
assumptions. Broadcasters Petition at
18–19; Webcasters Petition at 18–20, 52.
Finally, the Services argue that the
statute does not compel the Panel to
consider only negotiated agreements.
They also contend, that the reliance on
the fees paid for use of the musical
works in a prior CARP proceeding to
establish rates for subscription services
operating under the same license
required the panel to give more
consideration to the musical works
benchmark. Broadcaster’s Petition at 1–
2; Webcasters Petition at 1–2, 15, 17, 47.
Webcasters find support for this last
argument in an Order of the Copyright
Office issued in this proceeding, dated
July 18, 2001.
In that order, the Office acknowledged
that in 1998 it had adopted the rates
paid for musical works fees as a relevant
benchmark for setting rates for
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
subscription services. It stated, however,
that the evidence in that case did not
support a conclusion that the value of
the sound recording exceeded the value
of the musical work. Moreover, and
directly to the point, the Register’s
recommendation in the earlier
proceeding concurred with the earlier
Panel’s determination that the musical
works benchmark is NOT determinative
of the marketplace value of the
performance right in sound recordings.
The relevant passage states: ‘‘The
question, however, is whether this
reference point (the musical works
benchmark) is determinative of the
marketplace value of the performance in
sound recordings; and, as the Panel
determined, the answer is no.’’ 63 FR
25394, 25404 (May 8, 1998).
The July 18 Order went on to note
that in the subscription service
proceeding, ‘‘[h]ad there been record
evidence to support the opposite
conclusion, [namely, that the value of
sound recordings exceeds the value of
musical works], the outcome might have
been different.’’ This statement was an
invitation to the parties to provide
whatever evidence they could adduce in
this proceeding to establish the value of
the sound recording. It was not to be
read as an absolute determination, that
the value of the sound recording in a
marketplace unconstrained by a
compulsory license is less than the
value of the underlying musical work.
Instead, the Order stated that ‘‘the
musical work fees benchmark identified
in a previous rate adjustment
proceeding as the upper limit on the
value of the performance of a sound
recording may or may not be adopted as
the outer boundary of the ‘‘zone of
reasonableness’’ in this proceeding. This
is a factual determination to be made by
the CARP based upon its analysis of the
record evidence in this proceeding.’’
It is also important to note that in the
prior proceeding, the only reason the
Register and the Librarian focused on
the musical works benchmark was
because it was the only evidence that
remained probative after an analysis of
the Panel’s decision. Each of the other
benchmarks possessed at least one fatal
deficiency and, consequently, each was
rejected as a reliable indicator of the
value of the performance of a sound
recording by a subscription service. Of
equal importance is the fact that the
musical works benchmark had never
been fully developed in the record, nor
had any party relied on it to any great
extent in making its case to that Panel.
Consequently, it was not arbitrary for
the Panel to reject the Services’
invitation to anchor its decision for
setting rates for nonsubscription
VerDate May2002
17:45 Jul 05, 2002
Jkt 197001
services on the prior decision setting
rates for preexisting subscription
services.
Moreover, the Panel is not required to
justify why the rates it ultimately
recommended here are greater than the
rates preexisting subscription services
pay for use of the musical works. That
is merely the result of the analysis of the
written record before this Panel, and its
decision flows naturally from its
reliance upon contractual agreements
negotiated in the relevant marketplace
for the right at issue. This difference in
the rates is also attributable to the
different standards that govern each rate
setting proceeding. As discussed
previously in section IV.1, the standard
for setting rates for subscription services
is policy based and not dependent upon
market rates. Consequently, it is more
likely that the rates set under the
different standards will vary markedly,
especially when rates are being set for
a new right in a nascent industry.
Nevertheless, the Register agrees with
the Services on a number of theoretical
points. Certainly, the Panel could have
utilized Dr. Jaffe’s model in making its
decision, either alone or in conjunction
with the voluntary agreements,
provided that it considered the model’s
deficiencies, and made appropriate
adjustments for the fact that the model
required reliance on a string of
assumptions to perform the conversion
of a rate for the public performance of
a musical work in an analog
environment, into a comparable rate for
the public performance of a sound
recording in a digital format. See AMOA
v. CRT, 676 F2d 1144 (7th Cir. 1982).
But the fact remains that it was not
required by law to do so. The Panel was
free to choose any of the benchmarks
offered into the record or to rely on each
of them to the degree they aided the
Panel in reaching its decision. See, e.g.,
Use of Certain Copyrighted Works in
Connection with Noncommercial
Broadcasting, 43 FR 25068–69 (CRT
found voluntary license between BMI,
Inc., and the public broadcasters, Public
Broadcasting System and National
Public Radio, of no assistance in setting
rates for use of ASCAP repertoire).
The Register also rejects the Services’
contentions that the Panel failed to
consider fully Dr. Jaffe’s model. See
Webcasters Petition at 20, 52. The Panel
did consider Jaffe’s model and
concluded that it need not consider
alternative benchmarks that are at best
analogous when it had actual evidence
of marketplace value of the performance
of the sound recordings in the record.
Report at 42. It also rejected the offer to
utilize the model because the
underlying assumptions were in many
PO 00000
Frm 00009
Fmt 4701
Sfmt 4700
45247
instances questionable. For example, the
Panel did not accept the assumptions
that a percentage of revenue model
could be converted accurately to a per
performance metric, or that the buyers
and sellers in the two marketplaces are
analogous.
Broadcasters assert that they had
established that the value of the musical
work is higher than the comparable
right for sound recording based on the
fees paid for use of these works in
movies and television programs.
Broadcasters Petition at 24. In addition,
they offered a study of the fees paid for
these rights in twelve foreign countries
where the Services claim these rights
are valued more or less equally. Id. at
24, 49. Because the Panel failed to
analyze this information, the Services
argue, the Panel’s rejection of the
musical benchmark was arbitrary.
RIAA responds that the information
offered on the fees paid for the public
performance of sound recordings fails to
establish that in these countries sound
recordings are valued according to a
‘‘willing buyer/willing seller’’ standard.
RIAA Reply at 20, fn 36. In fact, many
of the countries surveyed evidently use
an ‘‘equitable remuneration’’ standard,
which courts have held not to be
equivalent to a fair market value.
Because it is not possible to ascertain
whether any of the rates offered in the
survey of foreign countries represented
a fair market rate, or that the rights in
these countries are equivalent to the
rights under U.S. law, the Panel was not
arbitrary in its decision to disregard this
evidence. The Register also concludes
that the Panel’s decision not to consider
master use and synchronization licenses
for use of musical works and sound
recordings in motion pictures and
television was not arbitrary. At best,
these licenses offered potential
benchmarks for evaluating the digital
performance right for sound recordings,
and they may well have been useful had
not actual evidence of marketplace
value of the sound recordings existed. In
any event, they did not represent better
evidence than the voluntary agreements
negotiated in the marketplace for the
sound recording digital performance
right.
b. Voluntary agreements. On the other
hand, the Panel articulated two
affirmative reasons for its focus on the
negotiated agreements. First, the statute
invites the CARP to consider rates and
terms negotiated in the marketplace.
Second, the Panel accepted the premise
that the existence of actual marketplace
agreements pertaining to the same rights
for comparable services offers the best
evidence of the going rate. Report at 43,
citing Jaffe Tr. at 6618.
E:\FR\FM\08JYR3.SGM
pfrm17
PsN: 08JYR3
45248
Federal Register / Vol. 67, No. 130 / Monday, July 8, 2002 / Rules and Regulations
But in choosing this approach, the
Panel did not accept the 26 voluntary
agreements at face value. It evaluated
the relative bargaining power of the
buyers and sellers, scrutinized the
negotiating strategy of the parties,
considered the timing of the agreements,
discounted any agreement that was not
implemented, eliminated those where
the Service paid little or no royalties or
the Service went out of business, and
evaluated the effect of a Service’s
immediate need for the license on the
negotiated rate. See Report at 45–59.20
Ultimately, it gave little weight to 25 of
the 26 agreements for these reasons and
because the record demonstrated that
the rates in these licenses reflect abovemarketplace rates due to the superior
bargaining position of RIAA or the
licensee’s immediate need for a license
due to unique circumstances. At best,
the Panel concluded that the rates
included in these agreements establish
an upper limit on the price of the digital
performance right, and where included,
the right to make ephemeral copies.
Report at 59.
RIAA objects to the Panel’s decision
to reject 25 of the 26 agreements on the
grounds that the Panel’s criticisms were
overbroad. RIAA Petition at 34.
Specifically, it claims that the Panel
mischaracterized its agreement with
www.com/OnAir (‘‘OnAir’’), arguing
that this Licensee paid substantial
royalties and its decision to enter into