Establishing secure connection… Loading editor… Preparing document…
Navigation

Fill and Sign the Travel Agent Quote Template Form

Fill and Sign the Travel Agent Quote Template Form

How it works

Open the document and fill out all its fields.
Apply your legally-binding eSignature.
Save and invite other recipients to sign it.

Rate template

4.7
53 votes
Paul Trampe Econ Journal Watch, Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007, pp 308-320. The EITC Disincentive: The Effects on Hours Worked from the Phase-out of the Earned Income Tax Credit Paul Trampe1 Abstract The biggest expansion to date of the Earned Income Tax Credit, legislated in 1993, was taking effect just as the welfare reform of 1996 was removing the federal entitlement to AFDC benefits and devolving the program to the states, resulting in a large drop in caseloads and spending on the program. As a result, the EITC has become the largest US assistance program to the poor in terms of dollars and in terms of number of recipients, surpassing AFDC (now Temporary Assistance to Needy Families or TANF) (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 1). Long neglected in academic literature, the program has been receiving a great deal of attention recently, particularly its incentives and disincentives to work. Researchers have focused on the incentives of phase-in of the program, however, and have been less precise about the phase-out. The EITC phase-in range, where benefits increase as income increases, would tend to encourage work, while the phase-out range, where benefits are withdrawn above an income threshold, would discourage work. This paper focuses on the phase-out. Most studies have not found solid evidence of discouraged work, but some of those papers have focused on the wrong population and two seem to have overlooked facets of their own data. The most thorough study of the phase-out, which did not find a discouragement effect from the increase in the EITC contained in the 1986 tax reform bill, has not been repeated for the much larger expansion legislated in 1993. After reviewing the literature on the issue I show a regression which does suggest an effect on hours worked for those in the EITC phase-out range from the 1993 expansion of the program, albeit a small effect. 1 Ph.D. candidate, School of Public Policy, George Mason University. Arlington, VA 22201. Econ Journal Watch 308 Earned Income Tax Credit The EITC in Brief The EITC was created in 1976 as part of an economic stimulus package. The idea grew out of theories from Milton Friedman and others that a negative income tax, such that poor families receive payments from the government which increase as their income rises, would encourage participation in the workforce by the poor. The idea was to reverse the perceived disincentive of traditional welfare programs which pay the most to those with zero income – i.e. those who do not work at all (Green 1968, 28). At first the program was quite small but it was expanded in 1984, 1986, 1988 and especially 1993, at which time the benefits were also indexed to inflation so in nominal terms it has continued to grow. Figure 1: The EITC for Single Parent - Two Child Families As of 2007, the program pays a benefit equal to 40 percent of income for the first $11,000 for families with two children ($4400 maximum benefit) and 34 percent of nearly $7900 income for families with one child ($2662 maximum benefit). In 2001 legislation intended to reduce the inherent marriage penalty in EITC moved the beginning point of the phase-out up $2000 for two-parent families. Therefore, the phaseout now begins around $14,400 for single parent families and $16,400 for two parents. 309 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe Above that threshold, families with two or more children lose 21 cents of benefits for each additional dollar of income (see Figure 1). One-child families lose benefits above the threshold at a rate of 16 cents per dollar of income. This means that a single parent family with two or more children receives some benefits until reaching $35,263 in income while a single parent with one child receives some benefit until reaching $31,030 income. Two parent families’ benefits are reduced at the same rates, so the benefits end at an income level $2000 above their single parent counterparts. It is a “refundable” tax credit meaning it is paid through the regular income tax system but if those eligible do not have any tax liability against which to take the credit (and most eligible do not) they receive cash from the government. As a kind of reverse withholding, it can be paid into the person’s regular paycheck, but most choose to receive it in one lump sum when filing an IRS form 1040 each year. Previous Studies: Labor Force Expansion The phase-in percentage being larger than the phase-out percentage means that the incentive is larger than the disincentive, but it also means that the disincentive covers a larger band of income and therefore affects more people. In fact, 65 percent of those receiving benefits have incomes in the phase-out range (Liebman 1998, 104). It is logical to ask which effect is greater. Does the program produce a net gain in work or a net loss? The literature appears to be unanimous in reporting that each expansion in the Earned Income Tax Credit has brought about an increase in labor force participation by single mothers with children. The bulk of the AFDC and EITC population is made up of such families, so scholars have studied that group to measure the effects. According to Nada Eissa and Jeffrey Liebman, labor force participation by single women with children, controlled for participation rates of single women without children who were not eligible for the EITC at that time, rose 2.4 percent after the EITC expansion contained in the tax overhaul of 1986 (Eissa and Liebman 1996, 616). An earlier paper by Eissa and Liebman bunched the three years before the 1986 reform and the three years after and found a 1.4 percent increase in labor force participation by single women with children (Eissa and Liebman 1995, 2). In a separate paper written by Liebman, he found that the participation rate of women with children increased from 72.7 percent in 1984 to 82.1 percent in 1996 with three major expansions of EITC in between (Liebman 1998, 97). In a 2005 paper which Eissa wrote with Hilary Hoynes they find that labor force participation by women with children, defined as any work over a 12 month period, shows a jump from 73 percent in 1984 to 85 percent in 2003 (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 12). They report that most of the change occurred between 1992 and 1999 as employment jumped 16 percent. Eissa and Hoynes state that there was not much change in labor force participation of single women without children during that period (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 12). Econ Journal Watch 310 Earned Income Tax Credit Eissa and Hoynes and other authors treating the changes of the mid 1990s do not mention one caveat, namely, that over this same time period, AFDC was being reformed with the main effect being to push recipients into jobs. Even before the 1996 welfare reform at the federal level, the states had been using the waiver process to introduce all of the same reforms that would later be enacted nationally. Therefore since the EITC expansion and the welfare reform were happening virtually simultaneously, separating the effects is very difficult. However, Robert Greenstein reports that survey evidence suggests that more than half of the increase in labor force participation is connected to the EITC expansion (Greenstein 2005, 3). Previous Studies: Hours Worked While there have been many studies detailing the positive effects on workforce participation of the phase-in of benefits, they have been much less systematic in studying the negative effects of the phase-out. Several studies address the negative effects by looking at the average number of hours worked by all single women with children regardless of income. The rationale for doing so is, as Eissa and Hoynes put it, “that about three quarters of single EITC recipients have earnings in the flat and phase-out regions of the credit – thus the expectation is that the EITC will reduce the number of hours worked by most eligible single taxpayers already in the workforce” (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 8). However, those in the flat range do not face a disincentive and the studies, including the one quoted above, use families from all income levels, those in the flat and phase-out ranges as well as the phase-in range and those outside the EITC program altogether. Of course it is also possible to observe what appears to be a disincentive throughout the income scale due to the simple fact that the subjective marginal benefit of each additional dollar of income declines as income rises. However, the disincentive directly attributable to the EITC does not affect all single women with children. The phase out of EITC benefits is only going to affect the level of work for those who are actually in the income range to which those marginal tax rates apply. In fact, for those in the phase-in range, an expansion of the program would be expected to cause an increase in hours worked due to an increase in the subsidy for each hour worked. Most papers on the subject do address the point that the disincentive only exists for those in the phase-out range but seem to regard it as a minor nuance in the data, when in fact it makes most of the studies doubtful for measuring the effects of that disincentive. Eissa and Liebman (1996), which I discuss below, was the one major study which focused exclusively on those in the phase-out income range. It found no effect and that seems to have settled the question for other researchers. Researchers have continued to conduct studies involving single women throughout the income range, but, since Eissa and Liebman (1996), no one has isolated the families actually affected by the phase-out range. 311 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe The literature is almost as unanimous in the claim that EITC has no disincentive effect on hours worked as it is on the claim that the phase-in encourages women to enter the workforce. One exception is a study by John Karl Scholz, who projected that the 1993 expansion would reduce hours worked by 21 hours per year for each family in the phase-out range (Scholz 1996, 159). He was making the prediction from his model of the labor market before the data was in, although the prediction was based on past responses by the labor market to changes in marginal tax rates. Jesse Rothstein (2007) reports that he could not find a difference in hours worked among women with children compared to women without. That study used the entire income spectrum (except zero, i.e. those who did not work at all), presumably including the phase-in range and those altogether beyond the EITC range. Bruce Meyer and Dan Rosenbaum (2001) found mixed results on hours worked for women with children – also using the entire income spectrum (Meyer and Rosenbaum 2001). Eissa and Liebman’s 1995 paper also found no decrease in hours worked by single women with children after the expansions of the 1980s (Eissa and Liebman 1995, 28-29). Again, none of these studies focused on the phase-out range. Three years later, in a single author paper, Liebman argues that studying the effects on hours for expansions other than the one legislated in 1986 is difficult because the changes in the program were phased in gradually (Liebman 1998, 100). After discussing the lack of empirical evidence for a decrease in hours among women with children, throughout all income strata, presumably, he then dismisses the idea that the Figure 2: Average Annual Hours Worked for Single Women in the Phase-Out Region of the EITC, 1984-2003 By Presence of Children Reprinted from Eissa and Hoynes 2001, 31. Econ Journal Watch 312 Earned Income Tax Credit study might yield different results if it focused solely on those with incomes in the phase-out range by referring back to his and Eissa’s 1996 paper (Liebman 1998, 104). More recently Eissa and Hoynes find “no evidence that hours of work decreased for single mothers relative to single mothers without children as the EITC expanded” (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 14). Although they do not focus on those in the phase-out range, they do include a figure, (reproduced here as Figure 2) specific to that group. The authors’ conclusion from this figure is as follows: “Strikingly, this figure shows no pattern of a reduction in hours worked for single women with children relative to single women without children” (Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 14). However, they do not comment on the dramatic increase in hours worked by single women without children starting in 1984 which was not accompanied by a similar increase for those with children. They also do not comment on the dramatic rise and subsequent fall in hours for those without children between 1997 and 2000 while the hours of those with children stay relatively constant. Interestingly there were no such divergence among all single women with children apparent in the Figure 3: Average Annual Hours Worked for Working Single Women by Presence of Children, 1984-2000 Reprinted from Eissa and Hoynes 2005, 30. figure Eissa and Hoynes print just one page earlier, reprinted here as Figure 3. In fact, between 1996 and 2000, hours worked appear to have increased faster for single women with children than for those without when looking at all incomes, whereas in the income range specific to the phase-out of EITC there was no increase at all for those with children but a dramatic rise in 1997 for those 313 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe without (the expansion of the program legislated in 1993 was fully implemented by 1996). Little wonder, then, that researchers basing their evaluations of the EITC phase-out on all single women with children get false results. For the years 19962000 at least, a researcher looking at all such families regardless of income would conclude that women with children increased their hours faster than those without. But those basing their conclusions only on families in the phase-out range would conclude the opposite, at least for the years 1996-1998. At least Eissa and Hoynes did include the figure in Figure 3, yet even they based their own conclusions on the total population of single women with children. The only other reference by Eissa and Hoynes to the issue of the phase-out range is, as by Liebman (1998), to refer back to the Eissa and Liebman paper of 1996 which will be discussed below. Eissa and Hoynes are not the only authors who seem to overlook facets of their own figure. One other method of determining whether the phase-out has an effect is to chart incomes to see if people tend to congregate at the “bend points” – i.e. just after reaching maximum benefits and at the end of the plateau range – just before the phase-out begins. Liebman’s 1998 paper included figures showing the distribution of households by income distribution separated according to whether they filed their income taxes in a joint return (married) or as a head of household (single with dependents), reproduced here as Figure 4. Liebman reports that “There is little if any bunching at the kink at the beginning of the EITC phaseout range” (Liebman 1998, 105). In the lower figure, for two-parent families, that is Figure 4: 1992 Distribution of Tax Returns for Taxpayers with Children Reprinted from Liebman 1998, 106 Econ Journal Watch 314 Earned Income Tax Credit certainly true. However, it is difficult to understand why Liebman does not see in the upper figure, representing single parent families, what plainly appears to be a concentration of incomes in the EITC plateau range (the rectangle just before the phaseout region). The implication of this figure would be that head-of-household taxpayers have learned how much they need to earn to gain the maximum EITC benefit and are able to arrange their hours such that they do not have to work extra hours for diminished after tax remuneration in the EITC phase-out range. However, Liebman is using IRS data which likely includes a great deal of fraud. The IRS spends much time making sure that all genuine income gets reported. It is much less practiced in making sure that all reported income is genuine. The only Americans with an incentive to over-report income are those in the phase-in range. There is believed to be considerable fraud in the EITC, and using IRS data may create a false appearance of bunching. In preparing this paper, I prepared similar figures using CPS data and did not find any bunching. The 1996 Eissa and Liebman paper presents the one extensive study of the effect on hours worked of the EITC on the phase-out range alone. The 1986 EITC expansion was unique in that, while the maximum benefit was increased, the phase-out range was decreased. The result was that the income range of the phase-out increased dramatically, from a range of $6500 to $11,000 before the expansion to a range of $8510 to $15,432 after. This created a large group of families subject to the EITC phase-out who had not been before. Eissa and Liebman used that fact to run a regression using a binary variable to differentiate between cases before the EITC expansion and after. The correlation coefficients (they ran more than one regression using populations defined more narrowly than just single women with children, e.g. single women without a high school diploma) came out positive, meaning single women with children in the new phase-out range increased their hours anyway; however, the 95 percent confidence intervals for the coefficients crossed zero, making the findings inconclusive (Eissa and Liebman 1996, 633). I regard the method to be sound, but it has not been repeated for later EITC expansions. Researchers have run new studies of hours worked by single women with children for all incomes, and they brush off questions about the phase-out with a reference to this one study, as if the difference between those in the phase-out range and those not is not an important distinction. Measuring the Effects of the 1993 Expansion on Hours Worked Therefore, I sought to create something along the lines of the Eissa and Liebman study of 1996, using, as they did, data from the Census Bureau’s Current Population Survey March Supplement, only analyzing the much larger increase in the EITC legislated in 1993. Unlike every previous study, however, I did not limit my sample to women. Most researchers base their study on single women with children because they make up the bulk of the EITC recipient population. How315 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe ever, those studies were primarily concerned with the phase-in and since most of them did not distinguish the income level, using female headed households was the only way to hone in on the EITC population. In the phase-out income range, which today reaches past $35,000 a year, female headed households are much less dominant. In the 600 randomly selected households for my study 197 were single parent households headed by women. I generated a random selection of 200 households with incomes corresponding to the phase-out range of the EITC from the 1993 survey, 200 from the 1994 survey, and 200 from the 2006 survey. The legislation passed in 1993, and that, therefore, was the last year before the increased phase-out rates. The legislation set 1994 and 1995 as transition years, though by 1995 the phase-out rates were nearly identical to the permanent ones. The three years I chose were the last year before the expansion of the program began, the transition year 1994, and the most recent year for which data was available. Rather than a before/after binary variable as Eissa and Liebman used, I established the EITC phase-out rate that applied for each household. Those in the 1993 survey with one child faced a 13.1 percent phase-out rate and those with more than one child a 13.9 percent rate. Among the households from 1994, they had a phase-out rate of 16 percent if they had one child and 17.7 if they had two or more. For those from the 2006 survey, the rates were 16 percent and 21 percent for one and two child families. Unlike Eissa and Liebman, I did not have a control group of people without children. My dependent variable in the regression was hours worked at all jobs last week. I controlled for age, gender, number of children, education level, whether or not the parent was currently enrolled in school (and if so whether it was part time or full time) and marital status. It should be noted that the Current Population Survey (CPS) has a seven point scale of marital status. As the point of including this item as a control variable is to account for the assumption that, for women in particular, unmarried individuals have to work more hours, the CPS scale was rearranged such that it was in the order of likelihood of receiving income from a spouse. CPS had number 1 as married and spouse at home – civilian, and number 2 married with spouse at home – military. For purposes of this study, this was not a meaningful distinction so 2 was recoded as 1. Also, CPS coded legally separated at number 6, above divorced or widowed. I recoded legally separated as number 3, since legally separated is closer to married than are divorced or widowed. Two cases, both from 1994 had to be dropped as the respondent apparently did not answer the question regarding hours worked last week. Further caution needs to be taken in recognizing the fact that the EITC phase-out is far from the only marginal tax rate faced by households in the sample. Those who are in the EITC phase-out income range and are also eligible for Food Stamps would be facing an income based phase out of Food Stamps as well. Those in public housing pay 30 percent of their income in rent. Those at the higher end of the EITC Econ Journal Watch 316 Earned Income Tax Credit phase-out range have liability under the income tax. Such factors alter work disincentives and are not controlled for here. I see no other significant data issues. Results The results of the regression are shown in Table 1. The EITC phase-out rate variable (eitcrate) carries a small but statistically significant (to the .05 level) negative coefficient. Although relatively small, the coefficient is important. Since the variable was entered as a number signifying the percent of income lost in benefits, the coefficient represents the number of hours per week a typical person in the phase-out range will forgo for each percentage point of marginal tax rate. The implication is that, all other factors being equal, the 1993 expansion of EITC caused those in the phase-out range to reduce their hours of work by 2.7 hours per week if they have two children (0.38 times a 7.2 percentage point increase in the phase-out range). Those with one child would be expected to reduce their hours by roughly 1.1 hour per week, as the phase-out rate was increased 2.9 points compared to 7.2 for two-child families. Measuring the effects of the entire phaseout disincentive, with a negative 0.38 coefficient, a person facing a 21.1 percent phase-out rate, all else being equal will reduce her work by 8 hours per week as Table 1: Effect on Hours Worked Source Sum sqs. dgs. fr. Mean sqs. Model 8995 7 1285 Residual 69083 590 117 Total 78078 597 130 Coef. Std. err. t P>|t| Beta Variable Number of obs = 598 F( 7, 590) = 10.98 Prob > F = 0.0000 R-squared = 0.115 Adj R-squared = 0.104 Root MSE = 10.821 age .08 .04 1.66 0.097 .065 sex -7.56 .97 -7.78 0.000 -.325 maritalst .68 .21 3.17 0.002 .134 children .21 .55 0.38 0.706 .016 -.28 .19 -1.25 0.211 -.049 enroll -9.44 3.46 -2.73 0.007 -.106 eitcrate -3.86 .18 -2.12 0.034 -.092 cons 59.63 8.23 7.25 0.000 education Data provided in link at Appendix. 317 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe compared to what they would be doing in the absence of the EITC altogether. It may seem unfair to estimate the implied effects of the entire program when most studies have reported only the effects of an expansion of the program. If the results from studies which show the positive effects on workforce participation from merely expanding the EITC are extrapolated we can see that the effect of the entire program must be enormous. If, as studies suggest, the 1993 expansion of the EITC reduced the unemployment rate for women with children by 12 percent, we can only assume that the effect as compared to the absence of the program altogether would be more than a quarter of that population working when otherwise it would not. Policy Implications This article, then, is not anti-EITC. Although the regression found a statistically significant negative effect from the phase-out of the program, that effect is dwarfed by the positive effect of the phase-in. It does indicate that families would be helped, and economic efficiency improved, if the disincentive from the phase out of the EITC can be reduced without harming those aspects of the program which encourage work. Opportunities to do that passed us by when the $500 per child tax credit was created and expanded to $1000. Because the EITC does not pay additional benefits for having more than two children, the $500 credit was made refundable only to the point where it cancels out payroll taxes that have not already been cancelled out by EITC payments, but only for families with three or more children. The dollar-width of the income range over which families do not have income tax liability against which to take the new credit but have enough earnings such that their EITC does not cancel out all of their payroll taxes is about $2500. Only families with more than three children in that narrow income band benefit from refundability of the $1000 credit. If, instead, the credit was made part of the EITC, but the $1000 per child remained a universal refundable credit, the EITC would only have to be phased down to that amount rather than to zero, enabling a smaller marginal tax rate in the phase-out income band. Furthermore, if the personal exemption for children were eliminated, the universal credit could be in the neighborhood of $1600 without reducing revenues to the government. Then only $1200 of the EITC amount for two children would have to be phased out and that could be done with perhaps a 5 percent rate without extending the phase out range much beyond the income level it reaches now. Replacing the current $1000 credit and personal exemption with a universal credit of $1600 would be a significant tax cut for low income families and a corresponding increase for those with children in the top brackets, for whom the personal exemption is worth more than for those in the lower brackets. Politically, this would be controversial. Econ Journal Watch 318 Earned Income Tax Credit Conclusion The original question was whether or not the positive incentives from the phase in of the EITC had a greater effect than the disincentives of the phase-out, given that the phase-in was a higher percentage but the phase-out affected more people. Previous researchers have focused on the positive effects and treated the phase-out more as an afterthought. Except for the landmark study by Eissa and Liebman (1996), researchers have also tended to ignore the fact that only those actually in the phase-out income range face the disincentive. Using hours worked, as some have, is bound to bring about mixed results since an expansion encourages those already in the phase-in range to increase hours. The study by Eissa and Liebman (1996) of the response to the 1986 expansion had not been repeated for later expansions. This paper conducted a study similar to Eissa and Liebman (1996), with some differences, surrounding the major expansion of 1993. The result was a small but statistically significant negative affect on work by those in the phaseout range. However, in answer to the original question, this effect appears much smaller than the positive effects on workforce participation found in numerous other studies. Therefore, on the whole, the EITC seems to encourage work – if I have doubts about that it would only be because we might be misled by fraudulently reported income in the phase-in range and unreported income in the phaseout range. Assuming the numbers are not terribly misleading, some changes to the program and integration with other tax advantages for families with children could make it an even more effective work incentive. Appendix The data from the 598 Current Population Survey cases used for Table 1 can be found here. Included is a brief explanation of the scale for variables that may not be self explanatory. Link. References Blumenthal, Marsha, Brian Erard, and Chih-Chin Ho. 2005. Participation and Compliance with the Earned Income Tax Credit. National Tax Journal 58(2): 189-213. Eissa, Nada, and Hilary Hoynes. 2005. Behavioral Responses To Taxes: Lessons From the EITC and Labor Supply. NBER Working Paper No. 11729. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Published in 2006 with the same title in Tax Policy and the Economy, 20: 74-110. Eissa, Nada, and Jeffrey Liebman. 1996. Labor Supply Response to the Earned 319 Volume 4, Number 3, September 2007 Paul Trampe Income Tax Credit. Quarterly Journal of Economics 111(2): 605-637. Eissa, Nada, and Liebman, Jeffrey. 1995. Labor Supply Response to the Earned Income Tax Credit. NBER Working Paper No. 5158. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research. Green, Christopher. 1968. Taxes and Monetary Incentives to Work: The Static Theory. The Journal of Human Resources 3(3): 280-288. Greenstein, Robert. 2005. The Earned Income Tax Credit: Boosting Employment, Aiding the Working Poor. Washington, D.C.: Center on Budget and Policy Priorities Liebman, Jeffrey. 1998. The Impact of the Earned Income Tax Credit on Incentives and Income Distribution. In Tax Policy and the Economy, Volume 12, ed. James Poterba, 97-107. Cambridge: MIT Press. Meyer, Bruce and Dan Rosenbaum. 2001. Welfare, the Earned Income Tax Credit, and the Labor Supply of Single Mothers. Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(3): 1063-1114. Meyer, Bruce. 2002. Labor Supply at the Extensive and Intensive Margins: The EITC, Welfare, and Hours Worked. American Economic Review 92(2): 373-379. Rothstein, Jesse. 2007. The Mid-1990s EITC Expansion: Aggregate Labor Supply Effects and Economic Incidence. Working Paper. Scholz, John Karl. 1996. In-Work Benefits in the United States: The Earned Income Tax Credit. Economic Journal 106(434): 159-169. About the Author Paul Trampe has worked for the federal government for 19 years, as an economist in the executive branch and an economic policy advisor in the legislative branch. He holds an MA in history from George Mason University and is currently enrolled in the Ph.D. program at George Mason’s School of Public Policy. His email is ptrampe@ gmu.edu. Go to Reply by Hilary Hoynes Go to September 2007 Table of Contents with links to articles Econ Journal Watch 320

Practical advice for preparing your ‘Travel Agent Quote Template’ online

Are you fed up with the burden of handling paperwork? Look no further than airSlate SignNow, the leading eSignature solution for individuals and small to medium-sized businesses. Bid farewell to the monotonous procedure of printing and scanning documents. With airSlate SignNow, you can effortlessly complete and sign documents online. Utilize the powerful capabilities embedded in this user-friendly and cost-effective platform and transform your document management strategy. Whether you need to authorize forms or collect signatures, airSlate SignNow manages it all effortlessly, with just a few clicks.

Follow this comprehensive guide:

  1. Log in to your account or register for a complimentary trial with our service.
  2. Click +Create to upload a file from your device, the cloud, or our form library.
  3. Access your ‘Travel Agent Quote Template’ in the editor.
  4. Click Me (Fill Out Now) to prepare the document on your end.
  5. Insert and designate fillable fields for additional users (if necessary).
  6. Proceed with the Send Invite configurations to request eSignatures from others.
  7. Download, print your copy, or convert it into a reusable template.

Don't worry if you need to collaborate with your colleagues on your Travel Agent Quote Template or send it for notarization—our solution provides you with everything you require to achieve these tasks. Create an account with airSlate SignNow today and elevate your document management to a new standard!

Here is a list of the most common customer questions. If you can’t find an answer to your question, please don’t hesitate to reach out to us.

Need help? Contact Support
Travel agent quote template word
Travel agent quote template excel
Travel quotation format in Word
Travel Agent Quote Template | Canva
Travel agent quote template pdf
Travel quote templates free
Sign up and try Travel agent quote template form
  • Close deals faster
  • Improve productivity
  • Delight customers
  • Increase revenue
  • Save time & money
  • Reduce payment cycles