Note
Free for the “Taking”: Why States Should Not Be Able to
Invoke Sovereign Immunity in Patent Infringement Disputes
Tanya Mazur*
“The patent system . . . added the fuse of interest
to the fire of genius.”
– Abraham Lincoln1
Introduction
There is a crisis looming on America’s horizon, whether in the
form of bioterrorism, an avian flu pandemic, or the bankrupting of the
federal government due to the aging population’s need for health
care. All of these crises demand widespread access to patented inventions, such as pharmaceuticals, to prevent the enormous suffering of
Americans. Emergency situations, such as the flu pandemic, will require production of patented products on a scale so massive that it
would require circumventing a patent’s normal protections.2 Even the
* B.S., Vanderbilt University, 1998; Ph.D., Chemistry, University of California, Berkeley,
2003; J.D., The George Washington University Law School, expected 2007. The author would
like to thank Dr. Robert H. Havlin for his thoughts and insights during the preparation of this
Note. The author would also like to acknowledge Articles Editor Brett Friedman for his helpful
comments and suggestions.
1 A. LINCOLN, Second Lecture on Discoveries and Inventions, in 3 THE COLLECTED
WORKS OF ABRAHAM LINCOLN 356, 363 (Roy P. Basler ed., 1953) (emphasis omitted). The
author viewed this quotation engraved on the U.S. Department of Commerce building in Washington, D.C.
2 See Matthew S. Bethards, Condemning a Patent: Taking Intellectual Property by Eminent
Domain, 32 AIPLA Q.J. 81, 115 (2004).
February 2007 Vol. 75 No. 2
398
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
399
aging baby boomer population’s need for access to low-cost prescription drugs through programs like Medicare could be considered an
emergency situation.3 Never before has the health and well-being of
our nation been so inexorably linked to patented inventions.
In recent years, Congress has attempted to address the coming
crises and has proposed a number of changes to the patent laws; these
changes, however, have failed to provide adequate solutions.4 States,
therefore, are becoming increasingly proactive with regard to their residents’ needs in these crisis situations and are beginning to look to a
loophole created by the Eleventh Amendment that exists in the patent laws.5 This loophole threatens to destabilize the United States’
incredibly successful patent system and the hundreds of years of technological innovation this system has provided to the nation.6
This Note examines the delicate balance between the public’s
need for ready access to patented goods and the patent protections
necessary to promote innovation, within the framework of the present
patent system. Also discussed in this Note are problems that result
from the approaches to patent “takings” and compulsory licensing
that states and local governments have begun to employ. This Note
proposes a vital amendment to the patent laws that would alleviate
the aforementioned crises while still encouraging innovation and protecting the basic tenets of the patent system. Furthermore, this Note
advocates that state sovereign immunity in patent cases be abrogated
to curtail states’ abilities to impose compulsory licenses upon patent
holders.
By allowing only Congress to wield the power to extract compulsory licenses, rather than state or local governments or officers or appointees of the executive branch of the federal government, this
proposal protects the sanctity and stability of the patent system. This
protection furthers the aims of the Constitution and fosters the progress of the useful arts and sciences. In cases of national emergency,
however, Congress would retain the authority to implement takings or
compulsory licensing of patents.
Part I provides background information regarding the U.S. patent
system. This Part discusses the balance between incentives for innovation and disclosure of information; mechanisms and rationales for pat3
See id.
4
See infra Part II.C.3.
5
See infra Part II.D.
6
See infra Part II.D.
400
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
ent exclusivity; and the condemnation of patents through both takings
and compulsory licensing.
Part II analyzes the necessity for striking a balance between promoting innovation and ensuring public health and safety. This Part
addresses the current authority of local, state, and federal governments to implement takings and compulsory licenses, and discusses
the historical implementation of compulsory licensing (including how
and why changes to the present system are necessary and where these
changes would have a positive impact). Finally, this Part analyzes the
threat that state sovereign immunity poses to the patent system and
explores why the system must be protected.
Part III proposes an amendment to the patent laws that would
abrogate state sovereign immunity in patent infringement cases. This
Part also explains how this amendment will meet the Supreme Court’s
“congruence and proportionality” test7 and how the amendment is
within Congress’s power under the Fourteenth Amendment.
I. Background
A. The U.S. Patent System: Procedures and Policy
1. Introduction to the U.S. Patent System
The U.S. Constitution states: “Congress shall have the power . . .
[t]o promote the Progress of Science and useful Arts, by securing for
limited Times to Authors and Inventors the exclusive Right to their
respective Writings and Discoveries.”8 This “exclusive right” grants
patent holders a “monopoly” of limited duration.9 The monopoly encompasses the inventor’s exclusive rights to make, use, offer to sell, or
sell her patented invention.10
To receive this protection, an applicant must meet a series of requirements imposed by statute and administered by the United States
Patent and Trademark Office (“USPTO”). To receive a patent, the
invention must be useful,11 novel,12 nonobvious,13 and must belong to
7
See Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627, 639
(1999).
U.S. CONST. art. I, § 8, cl. 8.
See 35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2) (2000) (granting patentees a term of exclusive rights for
twenty years from the date of filing).
10 Id. § 271(a) (stating that infringement occurs when someone other than the inventor
attempts to make, use, offer to sell, or sell the patented invention).
11 Id. § 101 (establishing the condition that the patented subject matter have a useful
purpose).
12 Id. §§ 101, 102 (providing the novelty requirement and prescribing what is considered
novel). Inventions are not deemed novel if they were previously in the public domain, if they
8
9
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
401
a valid category of patentable subject matter.14 If these criteria are
met and the patent is valid, the inventor is eligible to receive damages,15 an injunction,16 and possibly attorney’s fees17 if the patented
invention is infringed.18 The “right to exclude exists even if the infringing party developed the infringing product independently and
without knowledge of the patent.”19 In return for this privilege, the
inventor must disclose (or “enable”20), in a written description, the
best mode by which to perform the invention.21
2. Rationale for Granting Patent Rights
The patent system provides both an incentive to invest in developing new inventions and an incentive to disclose these inventions,
thereby increasing the domain of public knowledge.22 The incentive
were described in a printed publication older than one year, or if they were offered for sale in
the United States more than one year prior to submission of the patent application. Id. § 102(a);
see also PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, MANUAL OF PATENT EXAMINING PROCEDURE
§§ 2131–2133 (8th ed. 2001).
13 35 U.S.C. § 103 (noting that an invention would not meet the nonobviousness requirement “if the differences between the subject matter sought to be patented and the prior art are
such that the subject matter as a whole would have been obvious at the time the invention was
made to a person having ordinary skill in the art to which said subject matter pertains”).
14 Id. § 101 (permitting patents to issue for a “process, machine, manufacture, or composition of matter, or any new and useful improvement thereof”). Pharmaceutical substances and
chemicals qualify under the “composition of matter” prong. See Shell Dev. Co. v. Watson, 149 F.
Supp. 279, 280 (D.D.C. 1957) (stating that “all compositions of two or more substances . . . ,
whether they be the results of chemical union, or of mechanical mixture,” have been construed
as compositions of matter).
15 35 U.S.C. § 284 (allowing the wronged inventor to receive “damages adequate to compensate for the infringement, but in no event less than a reasonable royalty for the use made of
the invention by the infringer, together with interest and costs as fixed by the court”).
16 Id. § 283 (describing the circumstances under which a patent holder may be granted an
injunction).
17 Id. § 285 (permitting recovery of attorney’s fees only in “exceptional cases”).
18 Infringement occurs when another party, without the inventor’s permission, makes,
uses, offers to sell, or sells the patented invention. Id. § 271.
19 Daniel R. Cahoy, Treating the Legal Side Effects of Cipro: A Reevaluation of Compensation Rules for Government Takings of Patent Rights, 40 AM. BUS. L.J. 125, 131 (2002).
20 35 U.S.C. § 112 (detailing the enablement requirement). The enablement requirement
mandates that the patent specification state how to make and how to use the claimed invention.
Id. The enablement requirement also ensures that the claimed invention is communicated to the
public in a meaningful way. See id.; see also PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, supra note 12,
§ 2164.
21 35 U.S.C. § 112 (noting that the written description must be “in such full, clear, concise,
and exact terms as to enable any person skilled in the art to which it pertains . . . to make and use
the same, and shall set forth the best mode contemplated by the inventor of carrying out his
invention”).
22 See Kewanee Oil Co. v. Bicron Corp., 416 U.S. 470, 480–81 (1974) (“The patent laws
promote this progress by offering a right of exclusion for a limited period as an incentive to
402
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
to innovate is best explained by noting that without patent protection,
inventors “may be unable to appropriate enough of the social value of
the invention to justify the initial research and development expenditures.”23 Without patent protection, imitators would enter the market
and reduce prices to such an extent that an inventor could not recoup
his or her initial investment.24
In addition, the enablement requirement “ensures that useful
technology becomes accessible to the general public by putting it in
the public domain.”25 In the absence of patent protection, inventors
may maintain trade secrets to prevent competitors from exploiting
their ideas.26 It appears “likely that the patent system at least facilitates disclosure by creating rights in inventions that survive disclosure.”27 The benefits from conveying the knowledge associated with
new inventions include incentives for others to design around or improve the invention, thereby generating further innovation.28
In the United States, the patent owner’s right to exclude others
from making, using, or selling a patented invention extends even
where the owner is not “working”29 the patent or granting licenses to
others to “work” the patent.30 The Patent Act specifically states that a
patent owner is not guilty of misuse for “refus[ing] to grant a license
or use any rights to the patent.”31 The possibility exists, therefore,
inventors to risk the often enormous costs in terms of time, research, and development. The
productive effort thereby fostered will have a positive effect on society through the introduction
of new products and processes of manufacture into the economy, and the emanations by way of
increased employment and better lives for our citizens.”).
23 Rebecca S. Eisenberg, Patents and the Progress of Science: Exclusive Rights and Experimental Use, 56 U. CHI. L. REV. 1017, 1025 (1989).
24 See id.
25 Paul Gormley, Comment, Compulsory Patent Licenses and Environmental Protection, 7
TUL. ENVTL. L.J. 131, 133 (1993). Compliance with the enablement requirement provides the
information required for others to make, use, and sell the patented invention after the expiration
of the patent term. See id.; see also 35 U.S.C. § 112.
26 See Eisenberg, supra note 23, at 1028.
27 Id. at 1029.
28 See Cahoy, supra note 19, at 131–32.
29 In the context of patents, the term “working” is used to denote actions taken by or on
behalf of the patent owner to bring the patented good or service into the public domain prior to
the expiration of the patent term. See Gormley, supra note 25, at 134.
30 See id. at 134–35 & n.17 (contrasting the United States’ system with the United Kingdom’s patent laws, which require that the owner work the patent or risk the Comptroller of the
patents granting a compulsory license).
31 35 U.S.C. § 271(d)(4) (2000); see also Cont’l Paper Bag Co. v. E. Paper Bag Co., 210
U.S. 405, 425 (1908) (noting that if a patentee sees fit he can reserve the exclusive right of the
invention to himself, and he is “neither bound to use his discovery himself or to permit others to
use it”).
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
403
that the inventor may choose to withhold the patent from the public
domain entirely for the twenty-year patent term.32 This possibility undermines the public benefit arguments outlined above, at least until
the patent term expires. One way in which other countries, and the
United States to a limited extent, deal with this issue is through the
use of compulsory licensing.33
B. Limitations on Exclusivity of Patent Rights
There are two ways in which the government can condemn a patent.34 First, the government can “take” the entire patent, through its
eminent domain powers or by issuing a secrecy order.35 Second, the
government can force the patent owner to license the invention to
nonpatent owners. This second option is known as compulsory
licensing.36
1. Patent Takings: Secrecy Orders and Eminent Domain
Although the patent owner has exclusive rights regarding her patented invention, the exclusive nature of those rights is not absolute.
There are at least two means by which the government can limit these
rights: orders of secrecy and eminent domain.
Where a disclosed invention is “important to the armament or
defense of the United States,” an application can become the property
of the United States.37 In any instance where a patent is withheld by
an “order of secrecy and/or for the use of the invention by the Government,” however, the applicant can apply for or bring suit to gain
compensation for the damage and use of the patent.38
After the patent is granted, any limitations imposed by the government are governed by the Fifth Amendment.39 “[A]ny government action that affects existing patent rights—whether the act of a
32 See Gormley, supra note 25, at 135 (noting that “the long term gains of securing a
greater market share, or even of driving a competitor out of business, might well be of far
greater benefit to the patent holder” than exploiting the patented invention for the period of
exclusivity).
33 See infra Part I.B.2.
34 Condemnation is the “determination and declaration that certain property (esp. land) is
assigned to public use, subject to reasonable compensation; the exercise of eminent domain by a
government entity.” BLACK’S LAW DICTIONARY 310 (8th ed. 2004).
35 See U.S. CONST. amend. V.
36 See infra Part I.B.2.
37 35 U.S.C. § 267 (2000).
38 Id. § 183.
39 The Fifth Amendment provides that private property shall not be taken for public use
without just compensation. U.S. CONST. amend. V.
404
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
government employee that impacts a single patent or a congressional
act that retrospectively narrows the enforceability of all U.S. patents—is properly considered an appropriation of patent property.”40
Courts have long maintained that patents are subject to the eminent
domain power.41 More recent cases have noted that the government
maintains the power to take an invention when the public interest
warrants, as long as adequate compensation is provided to the patent
owner.42
When exercising its eminent domain powers, the government is
authorized, without the license or consent of the patent owner, to take
or use the patented invention.43 This ability extends even to cases
where the patented invention is being utilized by another for the
United States (e.g., a government contractor).44 In these cases, the
sole remedy available to the patentee is recovery of “reasonable and
entire compensation.”45 This precludes a patent owner from obtaining an injunction against future infringement by the government.46
One instance when the government may choose to condemn an
entire patent is during times of war.47 During World War I, it was
Cahoy, supra note 19, at 134.
See, e.g., James v. Campbell, 104 U.S. 356, 357–58 (1881) (“[T]he government of the
United States when it grants letters-patent for a new invention . . . confers upon the patentee an
exclusive property in the patented invention which cannot be appropriated or used by the government itself, without just compensation, any more than it can appropriate or use without compensation land.”).
42 See, e.g., King Instruments Corp. v. Perego, 65 F.3d 941, 950 (Fed. Cir. 1995) (discussing
28 U.S.C. § 1498). Some scholars argue that takings are not limited solely to the executive and
legislative branches. They argue that courts’ decisions in patent cases often effectuate “judicial
takings” and that the Takings Clause should encompass these acts, thereby requiring “just compensation.” See, e.g., J. Nicholas Bunch, Takings, Judicial Takings, and Patent Law, 83 TEX. L.
REV. 1747, 1752–69 (2005).
43 See Bunch, supra note 42, at 1752–54.
44 See 28 U.S.C. § 1498(a) (2000) (noting that “[w]henever an invention described in and
covered by a patent of the United States is used or manufactured by or for the United States
without license of the owner thereof or lawful right to use or manufacture the same,” the owner
can bring an action for recovery (emphasis added)).
45 Id. (stating that the patent holder’s “remedy shall be by action against the United States
in the United States Court of Federal Claims for the recovery of his reasonable and entire compensation for such use and manufacture” (emphasis added)). According to the statute,
“[c]ompensation shall include the owner’s reasonable costs, including reasonable fees for expert
witnesses and attorneys, in pursuing the action against the United States.” Id.
46 See Pitcairn v. United States, 547 F.2d 1106, 1114 (Ct. Cl. 1976) (“The nature of the
property thus taken is a license in the patent, the claimed invention of which is used or manufactured by or for the Government, and such license continues throughout the life of the patent, or
the period of the infringing procurement, whichever is shorter.”).
47 See Bethards, supra note 2, at 114 (noting that “in times of war, the government tries to
40
41
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
405
impossible to manufacture aircraft in the United States without utilizing the Wright48 and Curtiss49 patents.50 In 1917, the Aircraft Manufacturers’ Association was formed to “overcom[e] obstacles to the
production of airplanes arising from disputes between patentees that
were embarrassing the Government in its need for airplanes.”51 The
government agreed to pay royalties to the patent owners on each airplane that utilized the patents, whether manufactured by the government, purchased by the government from original subscribers to the
cross license, or purchased from nonsubscribers.52 Essentially, the
government created a patent pool to allow for relatively inexpensive
production of aircraft to be used in World War I.53 Although the
members of the Aircraft Manufacturers’ Association technically retained patent rights in their inventions, the government was the largest purchaser of aircraft.54 The patent owners, therefore, were only
receiving government-dictated royalties for their inventions rather
than the monopoly prices they would have received absent government-mandated patent pooling.55
Scholars note the possibility that national emergencies could also
justify the taking of an entire patent.56 For example, a taking, rather
than a compulsory license, would be useful in cases where an “outbreak required the treatment or vaccination of the entire U.S. populatake over an entire industry, including the associated [intellectual property]” and discussing
President Truman’s attempt to seize the nation’s steel mills).
48 U.S. Patent No. 821,393 (filed Nov. 23, 1903).
49 U.S. Patent No. 1,011,106 (filed Apr. 8, 1909).
50 This is distinct from the government issuing a secrecy order or withholding a patent
application. In this case, the patents had already issued to both Wright and Curtiss. Mfrs. Aircraft Ass’n v. United States, 77 Ct. Cl. 481, 514 (Ct. Cl. 1933).
51 Id.
52 Id. at 503.
53 As one scholar describes:
Prior to the creation of the patent pool, the Wright Brothers were asking
$1,000 per aircraft as a royalty (about 5 percent of the cost of a plane then) for a
single patent. The federal government forced patent owners to accept a $200 flat
fee for each airplane that was manufactured, and later lowered this to $100 per
plane. The royalties were divided 67.5 percent to the Wright Brothers, and 20 percent to the Curtiss-Burgess company, with the remainder used to support the [Aircraft Manufacturers’ Association]. The royalties to both the Wright and Curtiss
patent owners were reduced once they accumulated $2 million in royalty payments,
to $25 per airplane.
James Love, Consumer Project on Technology, An Essential Health Care Patent Pool (July 8,
2002), http://www.cptech.org/slides/jameslove-barcelona.ppt.
54 See Mfrs. Aircraft Ass’n, 77 Ct. Cl. at 514.
55 See id.
56 See Bethards, supra note 2, at 115 (2004) (speculating that a smallpox or anthrax outbreak “might justify the taking of an entire patent”).
406
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
tion” because “[e]veryone in the country would have used and
benefited from the technology, and there would no longer be a demand for a patented vaccine after the entire country ha[d] been inoculated.”57 One example of such a benefit occurred in the case of polio.
Widespread administration of vaccinations almost completely eradicated the disease in the United States over a period of five years.58
Although this did not involve a taking or a compulsory license because both Jonas Salk and Albert Sabin refused to patent their inventions,59 it is illustrative of the notion that once vaccines are
administered and the disease eradicated, the demand is substantially
diminished, if not eliminated entirely.
2. Compulsory Licenses
Compulsory licenses are distinct from patent takings. When a
patent is taken, in part or in its entirety, the patent owner does not
retain the rights to practice all or part of the patented invention.60
When the government or a court grants a compulsory license, the patent owner retains the rights to practice her invention and can still exclude others from doing so.61 Only the recipient of the compulsory
license can make, use, or sell the patented invention, and the recipient
must pay a reasonable royalty to the patent owner for this privilege.62
The government, by itself or through third parties, facilitates compulsory licensing to force the distribution of the invention to its citizens.63
57
Id.
See Bonnie A. Maybury Okonek, Development of Polio Vaccines (Linda Morganstein
ed.), http://www.accessexcellence.org/AE/AEC/CC/polio.html (last visited Nov. 12, 2006) (“In
1960, there were 2,525 cases of paralytic polio in the United States. By 1965, there were 61 . . . .
There has not been a single case of polio caused by the wild virus since 1979 . . . . In 1994, polio
was declared eradicated in all of the Americas.”).
58
59 James Stuart, Note, The Academic Industrial Complex: A Warning to Universities, 75 U.
COLO. L. REV. 1011, 1014 (2004).
60 This is analogous to a real property taking where the property owner can no longer
utilize the taken property. See Gormley, supra note 25, at 133–34.
61 The patent holder still has the right to make, use, offer to sell, or sell her patented
invention. Id. at 138.
62 See Dora Kripapuri, Reasoned Compulsory Licensing: Applying U.S. Antitrust’s “Rule
of Reason” to TRIP’s Compulsory Licensing Provision, 36 NEW ENG. L. REV. 669, 670 (2002)
(noting that “compulsory licensing generally represents a modest return on invested capital and
rarely includes the monopoly premium that a patent holder otherwise can receive by controlling
the supply”); see also J. THOMAS MCCARTHY, MCCARTHY’S DESK ENCYCLOPEDIA OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY 51–52 (1991).
63 Kripapuri, supra note 62, at 670 (referring to the price at which a license must be
offered).
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
407
The owner “is compelled to license at a rate thought to be ‘reasonable’ by the government.”64
The government and courts rarely employ compulsory licensing
under U.S. patent law.65 There are exceptions, however, and compulsory licenses have been issued in the areas of atomic energy,66 new
varieties of plants,67 and air pollution controls.68 The government and
courts generally employ compulsory licenses to advance some “political or social objective.”69 In addition, legislation that permits the federal government and its contractors to make or use any patented
invention70 essentially creates a “pseudo-compulsory license
provision.”71
Governments and courts choose to create compulsory licenses for
a variety of reasons.72 “Courts will often create compulsory licenses
when the patentee’s actions constitute an antitrust violation or patent
misuse.”73 A number of countries also employ compulsory licensing
when a patentee suppresses her invention.74 Compulsory licenses can
be granted for patents that “affect the public’s health, safety, environment, and national defense.”75 Strong public interest concerns are
MCCARTHY, supra note 62, at 51–52.
DONALD S. CHISUM & MICHAEL A. JACOBS, UNDERSTANDING INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY LAW § 4[E]7 (1992).
66 42 U.S.C. § 2183(g) (2000).
67 7 U.S.C. § 2321 (2000).
68 42 U.S.C. §§ 7401, 7608.
69 MCCARTHY, supra note 62, at 51–52.
70 See 28 U.S.C. § 1498 (2000).
71 See Alan M. Fisch, Compulsory Licensing of Pharmaceutical Patents: An Unreasonable
Solution to an Unfortunate Problem, 34 JURIMETRICS J. 295, 301 (1994).
72 See, e.g., Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights, Including Trade in Counterfeit Goods art. 31, Dec. 15, 1993, 33 I.L.M. 81, 95 (“TRIPS Agreement”)
(providing five grounds for granting compulsory licenses: (1) refusal to deal; (2) national emergency; (3) anticompetitive practices; (4) noncommercial use; and (5) dependent patents). Many
conditions must be fulfilled under the TRIPS Agreement before compulsory licenses are
granted, including: (1) review on individual merits; (2) previous efforts to authorize; (3) limitation of license to purpose for which it was authorized; (4) nonexclusivity; (5) nonassignability; (6)
predominant authorization for domestic market; (7) revocation; (8) remuneration; and (9) judicial review of remuneration. Cole M. Fauver, Comment, Compulsory Patent Licensing in the
United States: An Idea Whose Time Has Come, 8 NW. J. INT’L L. & BUS. 666, 668–74 (1988).
73 Bethards, supra note 2, at 105. Bethards also notes that in Europe, the patentee’s refusal to license an invention is seen as an antitrust violation. See id.
74 Bethards notes that the United Kingdom, Australia, and other countries in continental
Europe, Southeast Asia, and Latin American often employ compulsory licensing in these instances. See id. at 106–07; see also Gormley, supra note 25, at 133–36.
75 Bethards, supra note 2, at 110; see also Rite-Hite Corp. v. Kelley Co., 56 F.3d 1538, 1547
(Fed. Cir. 1995) (noting that courts can, “in rare instances, exercise their discretion to deny
injunctive relief in order to protect the public interest”); Sheldon Burshtein, Sublicense or Sup64
65
408
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
usually examined on a case-by-case basis.76 Other countries have also
employed compulsory licensing, or the threat thereof,77 in cases where
the price for patented goods is “too high.”78
When courts choose in their discretion not to enjoin infringement
for public policy reasons, these courts are effectuating a de facto compulsory license. Bethards notes several instances where courts employed this judicial tool.79 In City of Milwaukee v. Activated Sludge,
Inc.,80 the Seventh Circuit blocked an injunction that would have led
to the closure of a sewer plant.81 The court noted that allowing an
injunction would leave no means for disposing of raw sewage other
than into Lake Michigan.82 Although the patent owner could prove
infringement, the court elected not to issue an injunction for public
policy reasons such as those discussed in Bethards’s article.83
3. Patents as Personal Property
A final limitation can be imposed on patent rights because patents have the attributes of personal property and, therefore, are subject to similar rules regarding ownership and transfer.84 The
implications arising from the treatment of patents as personal property are numerous. One important implication is that the federal government creates and defines the scope of the property right.85
Essentially, “the government can create rules affecting the scope of
ply Agreement? Supreme Court of Canada Interpretation Benefits Generic Pharmaceutical Industry, 54 FOOD & DRUG L.J. 73, 74 (1999) (noting that until 1993, Canada required that all
applicants be granted a license “to practice an invention intended or capable of being used for
medicine, or for the preparation or production of medicine, unless there was a good reason not
to grant them a license”).
76 Bethards, supra note 2, at 111.
77 Brazil has employed the threat of compulsory licensing to obtain access to discounted
pharmaceuticals. See Intellectual Property: Patently Problematic, ECONOMIST, Sept. 14, 2002, at
75, 76.
78 The theoretical basis for this type of compulsory licensing is that compensation for a
license is based upon reasonable royalties rather than lost profits. See Bethards, supra note 2, at
111–12.
79 Id. at 110–12 (citing City of Milwaukee v. Activated Sludge, Inc., 69 F.2d 577, 593 (7th
Cir. 1934), as an example of a de facto compulsory license).
80 City of Milwaukee v. Activated Sludge, Inc., 69 F.2d 577 (7th Cir. 1934).
81 Id. at 593.
82 Id.
83 Id.; see also Bethards, supra note 2, at 110–12 (discussing the effects of water pollution
on public health).
84 35 U.S.C. § 261 (2000) (“Subject to the provisions of this title, patents shall have the
attributes of personal property.”).
85 Cahoy, supra note 19, at 132–33.
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
409
future grants without affecting any existing private property rights.”86
Congress, therefore, can limit the term of patent rights for patents
which have not yet been granted.87
II. The Importance of Ensuring the Stability and Uniformity of the
Patent System
As mentioned above, the patent system is designed to promote
innovation and progress in the useful arts.88 One mechanism by which
it does so is the grant of an exclusive right to the patent owner, for a
period of twenty years, to make, use, or sell the patented invention.89
In recent years, debate has raged over whether the government should
interfere with patent owners’ exclusive rights by granting compulsory
licenses.90
A. How Compulsory Licensing Disrupts the Economics of
Innovation
If the United States elects to preempt the exclusive patent right
through the grant of compulsory licenses for pharmaceutical patents,
for example, it could undermine the economic incentives to pursue
research and development in areas vital to the public welfare.91 “[I]f
the government uses its . . . powers to appropriate patent rights in
technologies related to important health or safety concerns (e.g.,
pharmaceuticals, antiterrorism technologies), one would expect to see
a corresponding reduction in investment and innovation in these very
fields.”92 Although this approach may solve immediate public health
crises, the long-term effects could be devastating. “The needs of a few
[individuals] for a period of ten [or twenty] years to obtain price pro86 Id. (noting that patent property rights do not exist until they are created by the act of
the government, through the USPTO, issuing a patent).
87 Cahoy analogizes this to a private landowner selling only a portion of his property. Id.
at 133–34.
88
See supra Part I.A.2.
89
35 U.S.C. § 154(a)(2).
Compare B. Zorina Khan, Federal Antitrust Agencies and Public Policy Toward Antitrust
and Intellectual Property, 9 CORNELL J.L. & PUB. POL’Y 133, 156 (1999) (“In general, analysts
and policymakers who propose remedies such as compulsory licensing demonstrate a failure to
understand the full implications of the economic model of induced innovation, a model that was
implicitly supported by the framers of the United States Constitution.”), and Fisch, supra note
71, with Fauver, supra note 72, and Gormley, supra note 25, at 133.
90
91
See Kripapuri, supra note 62, at 671.
92
Cahoy, supra note 19, at 170.
410
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
hibitive pharmaceuticals do not outweigh the needs of many others to
benefit from future pharmaceutical innovations.”93
Pharmaceutical companies must consider the potential for profit
when determining where to focus their research and development
budgets.94 Pharmaceutical research is financially risky; only one out of
every 4000 discovered compounds will ever become a marketable
pharmaceutical.95 The price of pharmaceuticals reflects a number of
factors, including costs associated with the 3999 compounds that fail to
reach the market and providing investors with “a rate of return on all
research commensurate with the investment’s high risk.”96 If compulsory licensing were to apply, it is likely that it would apply only to
“patent protected breakthrough pharmaceuticals, and that the scheme
would establish a licensing fee lower than lost profits, resulting in a
decline of income for the companies whose products are licensed.”97
In this position, pharmaceutical companies only have two choices: (1)
raise prices (on drugs not subject to compulsory licenses) or (2) reduce expenditures (usually in the form of research and development).98 Because the market will not bear increased costs,99 the only
choice for pharmaceutical companies is to reduce expenditures, which
often translates into a reduction in the creation of breakthrough
drugs.100
Some scholars cite the Canadian system to indicate why the
United States should not favor a compulsory licensing scheme.101
From 1923 until 1993, compulsory licenses were available for all patFisch, supra note 71, at 314.
See Martin J. Adelman & Sonia Baldia, Prospects and Limits of the Patent Provision in
the TRIPS Agreement: The Case of India, 29 VAND. J. TRANSNAT’L L. 507, 530 (1996) (discussing
how pharmaceutical research and development in India is focused on products that have the
largest domestic demand); Kripapuri, supra note 62, at 697.
95 See Fisch, supra note 71, at 303; John Schwartz, U.S. Drug-Testing Gantlet May Be
World’s Toughest, WASH. POST, Sept. 7, 1993, at A9.
96 See Fisch, supra note 71, at 303. Other factors include the introduction of a competing
product into the market, poor trial results, lack of acceptance by the medical community, invalidation of patents, or adverse side effects. Id.
97 Id. at 304 (defining a breakthrough pharmaceutical as one that treats a currently incurable condition).
98 Id.
99 See id. at 305–07 (discussing competitive markets and monopolistic markets and concluding that pharmaceutical companies cannot recoup the revenue lost to compulsory licensing
in either market).
100 See id. at 308–13 (discussing manners by which expenditures could be reduced and concluding that such a reduction in expenditures will inevitably lead to a decline in the number of
breakthrough pharmaceuticals).
101 See, e.g., id. at 313 n.104.
93
94
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
411
ented medicines in Canada.102 The royalty rate paid for this privilege
was between four and six percent of the selling price of the finished
product.103 Because the generic drug manufacturers targeted commercially successful drugs and did not incur any risks or expenses associated with research, drug innovators found that Canada’s compulsory
licensing system resulted in an inability to recoup investments in research and development costs.104 This made innovators reluctant to
patent new pharmaceuticals in Canada during this period.105
B. Why Compulsory Licensing Might Be the Answer
For those who advocate for compulsory licensing, the most compelling argument relates to issues of public interest. The price of
pharmaceuticals significantly impacts health care costs in the United
States.106 Many Americans cannot afford access to prescription
pharmaceuticals.107 Angela Jones, Executive Director of D.C. Action
for Children, testified before the D.C. City Council that “prescription
costs increased [at] four times the rate of inflation” and medical expenses are the cause of “more than half of all bankruptcy filings” in
the United States.108 When AIDS victims cannot access life-preserving pharmaceuticals, the value of a patent would seem paltry in comparison to these individuals’ suffering.109
There are also economic arguments that favor compulsory licensing, at least in the case of pharmaceuticals. Through widespread and
inexpensive public access to new medicines, compulsory licenses can
102 Burshtein, supra note 75, at 75 (noting that in 1993, as a result of the Canada–United
States Free Trade Agreement and the North American Free Trade Agreement, Canada amended
its Patent Act to eliminate compulsory licensing for medicines, but compulsory licenses that had
already been granted were grandfathered).
103 Id. at 74.
104 See id. at 74–75.
105 See Chris Warden, The Prescription for High Drug Prices, CONSUMERS’ RES. MAG.,
Dec. 1992, at 10, 12 (noting that from 1969 to 1989 there were only three new pharmaceuticals
introduced in Canada, while in 1991 alone thirty new pharmaceuticals were introduced in the
United States).
106 See Daniel R. Cahoy, Patent Fences and Constitutional Fence Posts: Property Barriers to
Pharmaceutical Importation, 15 FORDHAM INTELL. PROP. MEDIA & ENT. L.J. 623, 624–25 (2005)
(noting that U.S. consumers are paying more for pharmaceuticals than consumers in other industrialized nations).
107 See Prescription Drug Compulsory Manufacture License Act of 2005: Public Hearing on
Bill 16-114 Before the Comm. on Health (D.C. 2005) (statement of Angela Jones, Executive
Director, D.C. Action for Children).
108 Id.
109 See Johanna McGeary, Paying for AIDS Cocktails: Who Should Pick Up the Tab for the
Third World?, TIME, Feb. 12, 2001, at 54, 54 (asking “at what point does the human benefit to
desperate, destitute countries outweigh strict adherence to patents and profits?”).
412
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
translate directly into an “overall savings to the economy in productive lives saved.”110 Specifically in the case of AIDS, the vast number
of afflicted individuals leads to a decrease in worldwide productivity.111 Commentators such as Cole Fauver argue that an increase in
public access to inventions will increase competition and thereby further innovation.112 These economic arguments provide a marked
counterpoint to the notion that compulsory licensing stymies
innovation.
Finally, scholars have proposed equity arguments that favor compulsory licensing. They argue that it “allows inventors to receive a
reasonable royalty, but simultaneously discourages them from
preventing use of the invention. Such a system is fair to all parties
interested in the patented product or process.”113
C. Who Has the Authority to Implement Patent Takings or
Compulsory Licensing
1. Local Authority
It is not likely that a municipality114 would be able to take an
entire patent.115 Courts have, however, upheld the taking of patent
licenses by municipalities in certain limited circumstances.116
Most recently, an attempt by a municipality to employ compulsory licensing of pharmaceuticals was thwarted by the U.S. District
Kripapuri, supra note 62, at 693.
See id. (noting that thirty-five million people worldwide are infected with AIDS).
112 See Fauver, supra note 72, at 667–68.
113 Gormley, supra note 25, at 163.
114 It is important to note that the doctrine of sovereign immunity available to states does
not apply to political subdivisions of states such as counties, cities, or municipalities. See U.S.
CONST. amend. XI; Mt. Healthy City Sch. Dist. Bd. of Educ. v. Doyle, 429 U.S. 274, 280 (1977)
(“The bar of the Eleventh Amendment to suit in federal courts extends to States and state officials in appropriate circumstances . . . but does not extend to counties and similar municipal
corporations.” (citation omitted)). Therefore, determining whether an infringer is a political
subdivision or an entity of the state determines whether the infringer can be enjoined or required to pay treble damages for willful infringement. See Hander v. San Jacinto Junior Coll.,
519 F.2d 273, 278–79 (5th Cir. 1975) (“[M]ere ‘political subdivisions’ of the state do not enjoy
constitutional immunity.”). Municipalities, counties, and other arms of local government not
protected by the Eleventh Amendment do not, therefore, present insurmountable problems to
patent holders attempting to protect their exclusive rights.
115 See Bethards, supra note 2, at 96 (stating that this would “so substantially burden the
interests of the municipality/patentee and its relevant public that it would never seem justified”).
116 See, e.g., City of Milwaukee v. Activated Sludge, Inc., 69 F.2d 577, 593 (7th Cir. 1934)
(awarding the municipality a compulsory license to preserve the health and safety of the citizens
of Milwaukee). For a further discussion of Activated Sludge, see supra notes 80–83 and accompanying text.
110
111
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
413
Court for the District of Columbia.117 The D.C. City Council determined that the “excessive prices of prescription drugs [were] threatening the health and welfare of [its] residents . . . and these excessive
prices directly and indirectly cause[d] economic harm to the District
and damage[d] the health and safety of its residents.”118 As a result,
the District enacted a bill that made it “unlawful for any drug manufacturer . . . to sell or supply for sale or impose minimum resale requirements for a patented prescription drug that results in the
prescription drug being . . . sold in the District for an excessive
price.”119
The court held that the District of Columbia’s Prescription Drug
Excessive Pricing Act (“Act”)120 was preempted by federal patent
laws relating to prescription drugs and had a per se invalid extraterritorial reach in violation of the Commerce Clause.121 The court found
that the Act violated the Supremacy Clause because it presented an
obstacle to Congress’s objectives in passing the patent laws regarding
pharmaceuticals.122 “Congress’ regulation of our nation’s pharmaceutical industry is grounded in large part in a complex balance of economic forces and regulatory exclusivity designed to encourage and
reward the innovation, research, and development of new drugs.”123
The court noted that this Act would “[p]unish[ ] the holders of pharmaceutical patents.”124 After this decision, it is not likely that attempts by other municipalities to enact similar legislation will pass
constitutional muster.
117 See Pharm. Research & Mfrs. of Am. v. Dist. of Columbia, 406 F. Supp. 2d 56, 72
(D.D.C. 2005).
118 Id. at 59 (quotation omitted).
119 Prescription Drug Excessive Pricing Act of 2005, 2005 D.C. Sess. Law Serv. 2–3 (West).
120 Prescription Drug Excessive Pricing Act of 2005, 2005 D.C. Sess. Law Serv. 2–3 (West).
121 See Pharm. Research & Mfrs. of Am., 406 F. Supp. 2d at 70 (stating there was “no
question that the D.C. Act was intended to and will control out-of-state conduct”).
122 Id. at 64.
123 Id. at 65–66 (noting that the Patent Term Restoration Act, 35 U.S.C. § 156, was a result
of compromises between various industries involved, people affected, senior citizens, generic
pharmaceuticals manufacturers, and patent owners); see also Bonito Boats, Inc. v. Thunder Craft
Boats, Inc., 489 U.S. 141, 150–51 (1989) (noting that the patent system “embodies a carefully
crafted bargain for encouraging the creation and disclosure of new, useful, and nonobvious advances in technology and design in return for the exclusive right to practice the invention for a
period of years”).
124 Pharm. Research & Mfrs. of Am., 406 F. Supp. 2d at 66.
414
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
2. State Authority
Generally speaking, governments cannot take property outside of
their jurisdictions. In the case of patents, however, there are no defined territorial limits.125 The Commerce Clause prevents a state from
taking an entire patent by eminent domain. In the case of a compulsory license, however, the Supreme Court has allowed takings.126
In Florida Prepaid Postsecondary Education Expense Board v.
College Savings Bank,127 the Supreme Court held that the State of
Florida never consented to suit for patent infringement.128 The Eleventh Amendment barred the suit, and the Supreme Court dismissed
the case because there were no grounds upon which the patent infringement claim could proceed.129 Although Congress had expressly
attempted to abrogate states’ patent infringement immunity130 by enacting the Patent and Plant Variety Protection Remedy Clarification
Act (“Patent Remedy Act”),131 the Act was ruled unconstitutional.132
The State of Florida, therefore, was able to avoid suit while effectively
taking a compulsory license.133
This result is extremely troubling and will be addressed in more
detail in Part II.D. This Note argues that the ability of states to claim
compulsory licenses while avoiding suit in federal court (as a result of
sovereign immunity), poses significant risks to the integrity of the U.S.
patent system. As will be discussed, this result has already begun to
threaten the delicate balance that exists between the promotion of innovation and the public good.134
3. Federal Authority
As previously discussed, the federal government retains the eminent domain authority under the Fifth Amendment to take a valid
125
126
See Bethards, supra note 2, at 90.
See Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627, 630
(1999).
Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627 (1999).
Id. at 630–31. In the case, a New Jersey–based College Savings Bank brought an infringement action against a Florida state agency for its alleged use of a patented apparatus and
method for administering a college investment program. Id.
129 See id. at 647–48.
130 The Eleventh Amendment immunizes states from “any suit in law or equity.” U.S.
CONST. amend. XI.
131 Patent and Plant Variety Protection Remedy Clarification Act, Pub. L. No. 102-560, 106
Stat. 4230 (1992) (codified in scattered sections of 7 and 35 U.S.C.).
132 See Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 527 U.S. at 648.
133 See id.
134 See infra Part II.D.
127
128
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
415
patent or a compulsory license thereof for a public use.135 When the
federal government exercises this power, it waives its governmental
immunity from suit.136 Thus, the federal government consents to suit
in the U.S. Court of Federal Claims for “reasonable and entire compensation” for the use or manufacture of the patented invention.137
Although the patent owner cannot enjoin the federal government
from infringement, she can obtain damages.138 The fact that the federal government retains this right seems logical as it is the federal government, through the USPTO, that grants the property rights
associated with patents.139
As one court has noted, however, Congress is in the best position
to fully understand and appreciate the “complex balance of economic
forces and regulatory exclusivity designed to encourage and reward . . . innovation, research and development.”140 This understanding is borne out by the fact that Congress presently only takes
compulsory licenses in a few limited areas: atomic energy inventions,141 certain new varieties of plants,142 and certain air pollution
control inventions.143 Historically, Congress has limited itself with regard to compulsory licensing as well.144
There have been several attempts by the U.S. House of Representatives to provide for compulsory licensing of patents relating to
health care emergencies, such as pharmaceutical patents.145 The most
See supra Part I.B.
See 28 U.S.C. § 1498(a) (2000) (“For the purposes of this section, the use or manufacture of an invention described in and covered by a patent of the United States by a contractor, a
subcontractor, or any person, firm, or corporation for the Government and with the authorization or consent of the Government, shall be construed as use or manufacture for the United
States.”).
137 Id.
138 Id. § 1498.
139 Bethards, supra note 2, at 89 (“The patentee takes his patent from the United States
subject to the government’s eminent domain rights to obtain what it needs from manufacturers
and to use the same.” (quotation omitted)).
140 Pharm. Research & Mfrs. of Am. v. Dist. of Columbia, 406 F. Supp. 2d 56, 65 (D.D.C.
2005).
141 42 U.S.C. § 2183(g) (2000).
142 7 U.S.C. § 2321 (2000).
143 42 U.S.C. §§ 7401, 7608.
144 The only historical implementation of a government-imposed compulsory licensing
scheme was during World War I to allow for the manufacture of aircraft. See supra note 53 and
accompanying text.
145 See, e.g., Public Health Emergency Medicines Act, H.R. 4131, 109th Cong. (2005) (reintroduction of a November 2001 bill); To Provide for the Importation of Pharmaceutical Products
Under a Compulsory License as Provided for Under the World Trade Organization, H.R. 4392,
109th Cong. (2005).
135
136
416
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
recent bill grants the government authority to take a compulsory license for the production of Tamiflu, a pharmaceutical believed to be
most effective in combatting the bird flu.146 The bill further authorizes
the President “to import pharmaceutical products manufactured
under a compulsory license to meet public health needs or to address
situations of inadequate supply caused by insufficient domestic manufacturing capacity.”147 Although the President would administer the
importation of the necessary pharmaceuticals, Congress retains the
authority to grant the compulsory license,148 thereby maintaining the
balance between promoting innovation and providing for the public
welfare in national health crises. Instances where the federal government elects to take a compulsory license do not, therefore, pose the
same dangers as state-by-state compulsory licensing.
D. How State Sovereign Immunity in Patent Cases Undermines
Necessary Incentives for Research and Development
As mentioned briefly above, state sovereign immunity presents a
number of problems in the context where the state is either a direct or
contributory patent infringer.149 One problem relates to the fact that
the state avails itself of patent protections, but remains insulated from
potential suit.150 Another problem occurs when individual states act
to take compulsory licenses for the benefit of their citizens. Congress
has sought to abrogate this immunity in the context of patent infringement to ensure the stability of the patent system.151 Unfortunately,
the Supreme Court found that the measures taken by Congress were
unconstitutional.152 This holding has left a loophole through which
states can act as patent infringers and, by refusing to consent to suit,
take compulsory licenses for an unlimited number of U.S. patents.
An equity problem arises when states are able to avail themselves
of federal patent protections without having to waive their sovereign
immunity for patent infringement. Unlike the states, the federal government explicitly waives its sovereign immunity in cases where it
H.R. 4392.
Id. § 3.
148 H.R. 4392.
149 See supra Part II.C.2.
150 See Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627, 657
(1999) (Stevens, J., dissenting) (“States and their instrumentalities are heavily involved in the
federal patent system.”).
151 See Patent and Plant Variety Protection Remedy Clarification Act, 35 U.S.C. §§ 271(h),
296(a) (1994), invalidated by Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 527 U.S. 627.
152 See Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 527 U.S. at 647–48.
146
147
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
417
manufactures or uses a patented invention.153 States are, however, increasingly utilizing patent protections for their own interests while retaining sovereign immunity in patent infringement disputes.
In 1995, more than 362 utility patents154 were issued to state universities,155 and royalty earnings from licenses at U.S. universities totalled $273.5 million, a twelve-percent increase over the prior year.156
In 2004, more than 630 utility patents were issued to state universities.157 The evidence indicates that states are availing themselves of
the patent system as a means of generating revenues. This lack of
equity in the present system arises from the states’ sovereign immunity in patent infringement cases.
Congress has long been concerned with state sovereign immunity
as it applies to patent infringement suits. In 1992, Congress amended
the patent laws, with the Patent Remedy Act, to expressly remove
states’ sovereign immunity from claims regarding patent infringement.158 The Patent Remedy Act stated that
[a]ny State, any instrumentality of a State, and any officer or
employee of a State or instrumentality of a State acting in his
official capacity, shall not be immune, under the eleventh
amendment of the Constitution of the United States or
under any other doctrine of sovereign immunity, from suit in
Federal court by any person . . . for infringement of a patent
under section 271, or for any other violation under this
title.159
See 28 U.S.C. § 1498(a) (2000).
A utility patent is the type of patent most commonly granted. Utility patents are issued
for inventions that perform useful functions. This is in contrast to design patents that only protect the appearance of a claimed invention or plant patents that cover newly engineered or discovered plant types. See Joseph Scott Miller & James A. Hilsenteger, The Proven Key: Roles and
Rules for Dictionaries at the Patent Office and the Courts, 54 AM. U. L. REV. 829, 838 n.28 (2005).
155 U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, PATENTING BY ORGANIZATIONS 8–29 (1995),
http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/topo_95.pdf. The report lists organizations that
received more than thirty utility patents during 1995. Some notable grantees were the University of California system (213 patents), University of Texas (89), University of Michigan (30), and
North Carolina State University (30). Id.
156 2 ECKSTROM’S LICENSING IN FOREIGN AND DOMESTIC OPERATIONS § 11.06 (David M.
Epstein ed., 1998).
157 U.S. PATENT & TRADEMARK OFFICE, PATENTING BY ORGANIZATIONS 7–27 (2004),
http://www.uspto.gov/web/offices/ac/ido/oeip/taf/topo_04.pdf. The report also lists organizations
receiving more than forty utility patents during 2004, including the University of California system (422 patents), University of Texas (99), University of Michigan (66), University of Illinois
(58), University of Minnesota (43), and North Carolina State University (42). Id.
158 See 35 U.S.C. § 296(a) (1994), invalidated by Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense
Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627 (1999).
159 Id.
153
154
418
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
The Federal Circuit agreed with Congress’s reasoning and determined
that “significant harm results from state infringement of patents.”160
The Supreme Court, however, found that Congress had exceeded its
authority both under its Article I powers,161 and in attempting to secure Fourteenth Amendment protections against deprivation of property without due process of law.162
The Fourteenth Amendment provides that “[n]o State shall . . .
deprive any person of life, liberty, or property, without due process of
law.”163 Furthermore, it states that “Congress shall have the power to
enforce, by appropriate legislation, the provisions of this article.”164
The Supreme Court has held that Congress has the authority to abrogate state sovereign immunity pursuant to the Fourteenth Amendment through appropriate legislation.165 In City of Boerne v. Flores,166
the Court determined whether Congress had the power to enact given
legislation under Section 5 of the Fourteenth Amendment. There the
Court held that to enact legislation pursuant to the Fourteenth
Amendment, Congress must “identify conduct transgressing” the substantive provisions of the Fourteenth Amendment “and must tailor its
legislative scheme to remedying or preventing such conduct.”167 In
the case of the Patent Remedy Act, the Court found that Congress did
not identify a pattern of patent infringement by the states.168
The Court has further noted that “a State’s infringement of a patent . . . does not by itself violate the Constitution.”169 It is only when
the state does not provide a remedy, or provides insufficient remedies,
to patent owners that a due process violation occurs.170 With regard to
due process claims, the Court found that “[t]he need for uniformity in
the construction of patent law is undoubtedly important,” but that fac160 Coll. Sav. Bank v. Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 148 F.3d 1343,
1353–54 (Fed. Cir.), rev’d & remanded by 527 U.S. 627 (1998).
161 Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd. v. Coll. Sav. Bank, 527 U.S. 627, 636
(1998) (“[T]he Patent Remedy Act cannot be sustained under either the Commerce Clause or
the Patent Clause.”). Neither the Federal Circuit nor the respondents disagreed with this assertion. See id.
162 See id. at 636–48.
163 U.S. CONST. amend. XIV, § 1.
164 Id. § 5.
165 See Fitzpatrick v. Bitzer, 427 U.S. 445, 456 (1976).
166 See City of Boerne v. Flores, 521 U.S. 507, 519–20 (1997).
167 Fla. Prepaid Postsecondary Educ. Expense Bd., 527 U.S. at 639 (discussing City of
Boerne, 521 U.S. at 519–20).
168 Id. at 641, 642–43 (“[D]eprivation by state action of a constitutionally protected interest . . . is not in itself unconstitutional . . . .”).
169 Id. at 643.
170 Id.
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
419
tor does not influence “whether a state plea of sovereign immunity
deprives a patentee of property without due process of law.”171
Finally, the Court criticized Congress for failing to tailor its legislation to prevent intentional or reckless infringement by the states.172
The Court, therefore, held that Congress lacked the authority to enact
the Patent Remedy Act.173 Through this holding, the Court raised the
possibility that states, by employing sovereign immunity, could take
compulsory licenses without just compensation, something that local
and federal governments cannot do. This creates a problem with farreaching implications.
III. New Legislation Proposed to Abrogate State Sovereign
Immunity in Patent Infringement Actions
This portion of the Note proposes a framework and suggests language for an amendment to the patent laws that would abrogate state
sovereign immunity while passing constitutional muster.174 The proposed amendment responds to the Supreme Court’s constitutional
concerns regarding previous attempts to abrogate state sovereign immunity. Since the Court’s decision in Florida Prepaid Postsecondary
Education Expense Board v. College Savings Bank, much has occurred
to indicate that the enactment of such an amendment is within Congress’s powers under the Fourteenth Amendment.
A. Language of the Proposed Legislation
The purpose of the proposed amendment is to:
(1) abrogate state sovereign immunity solely in cases where
states or their instrumentalities, officers, or employees
infringe federal patents;
(2) assert the viability of relief against state officials who are
violating or contributing to the violation of federal patents; and
(3) promote innovation through the uniform protection of
federal patent rights.
Id. at 645.
See id. (“[N]egligent conduct . . . does not violate the Due Process Clause of the Fourteenth Amendment.”).
173 Id. at 647–48.
174 Legislation has been proposed in the Senate that would prevent a state from receiving
remedies in any suit it brings for patent infringement unless the state agrees to waive its sovereign immunity in patent infringement cases. See S. 2031, 107th Cong. (2002); S. 1191, 108th
Cong. (2003).
171
172
420
The George Washington Law Review
[Vol. 75:398
INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY STATE SOVEREIGN IMMUNITY
ABROGATION ACT
AMENDMENT TO PATENT LAW – Section 271 of title 35,
United States Code is amended by the following:
‘(h)(1) As used in this section, the term “whoever” includes any
State, any instrumentality of a State, and any officer or employee of a
State or instrumentality of a State acting in his official capacity. Any
State, and any such instrumentality, officer, or employee, shall be subjected to the provisions of this title if they are violating the provisions
of this section non-negligently. This shall include contributory
violations.
‘(h)(2) Non-negligent infringement will be found if the State, or
any such instrumentality, officer, or employee of the State, continues to
engage in patent infringement after being put on notice by the patent
owner or his assigns.’
AMENDMENT TO PATENT LAW – Section 296 of title 35,
United States Code is amended by the following:
‘(a)(1) Any State, any instrumentality of a State, and any officer
or employee of a State or instrumentality of a State acting in his official capacity, shall not be immune, under the Eleventh Amendment of
the Constitution of the United States or under any other doctrine of
sovereign immunity, from suit in Federal court by any person, including any governmental or nongovernmental entity, for non-negligent infringement, or non-negligent contributory infringement, of a patent
under section 271, or for any other non-negligent violation under this
title.
‘(a)(2) Non-negligent infringement will be found if the State, or
any such instrumentality, officer, or employee of the State, continues to
engage in patent infringement after being put on notice by the patent
owner or his assigns.
‘(b) In a suit described in subsection (a) for a violation described
in that subsection, remedies (including remedies both at law and in
equity) are available for the violation to the same extent as such remedies are available for such a violation in a suit against any private entity. Such remedies include damages, interest, costs, and treble
damages under section 284, attorney fees under section 285, and the
additional remedy for infringement of design patents under section
289.’
2007]
Free for the “Taking”
421
B. The Proposed Amendment Is Within the Scope of Congress’s
Power Under the Fourteenth Amendment
1. Congress Has the Power to Statutorily Limit the States’
Eleventh Amendment Rights
For the proposed legislation to be constitutional, Congress must
have the ability to statutorily limit states’ Eleventh Amendment
rights. The Eleventh Amendment provides that “[t]he Judicial power
of the United States shall not be construed to extend to any suit in law
or equity, commenced or prosecuted against one of the United States
by Citizens of another State.”175 Under the Eleventh Amendment,
each state is viewed as a sovereign entity, and “inherent in the nature
of sovereignty” is the notion that a state must consent to suit.176 Although Eleventh Amendment jurisprudence has significantly limited
Congress’s power to abrogate states’ sovereign immunity,177 there is a
notable exception. The Supreme Court has proposed a two-part inquiry to determine whether Congress has validly exercised an abrogation of state sovereign immunity.178 If Congress has “unequivocally
expresse[d] its intent to abrogate the immunity,” and if it